Evidence of Weakness in SEQ2001's Economic Vision
No criteria were defined for targeting 'growth' industries for the
region:
- What are the characteristics of desirable industries? It appears that
growth potential was given priority, but that productivity was not. Attempts
to analyse 'strategic' industries elsewhere tend to regard both criteria as
important (eg Pappas Carter Evans & Koop, Identifying Priority
Sectors, DITR, Victoria, Aug 1989). Further, if Australia as a whole is
to maintain the fast economic growth (>4% pa) which is required to reduce
unemployment, rapid improvement in productivity will be required to prevent
balance of payments problems leading to another 'recession we have to have'
(An oversimplified explanation is that imports increase in line with GDP
growth, and create a balance of payments deficit unless exports increase as
fast or faster. Competitiveness requires increasing productivity if wage and
exchange rates are not to be sacrificed. Servicing Australia's foreign debts
will increase this requirement when interest rates recover);
- a major focus in both the Industry Location and Tourism papers
was on industries which could 'create jobs' without visible concern for
whether they would also reverse the steady decline in community affluence.
Though wealth creation was identified as a goal, one can not serious expect
committees or government or tertiary education bodies to take the lead role
(as was suggested). Leading roles must be taken by those who have the
detailed market knowledge to detect opportunities early; and can manage
commercial risk;
- the Industry Location and Tourism position paper makes use of an
input / output analysis to show the employment impact of the growth of
various targeted industries, and correlate this with population projections.
But this is merely a forecast of what will happen if the economy remains
undeveloped, as economic development would change the parameters in any such
model. Furthermore, the industries which have good growth and job creating
potential depend greatly on how the economy is developed;
- the Industry Location and Tourism position paper discussed the
difference between wealth creating industries (assumed to be agricultural
and mineral production, manufacturing, tradeable services and tourism) and
wealth redistributing industries. In fact all industries are wealth
creators, to an extent which depends on their productivity. The basic
industries of a region (ie those in which the region competes successfully
with other regions) have often been seen those in which it is relatively the
most productive. As indicated in Section 5.2, SE Queensland's problem is
that its low level of economic development means that its comparative
advantages are in relatively low productivity activities;
Some targeted growth sectors appear to require re-consideration:
- education and training (whilst essential) would appear likely to be low
productivity sectors in themselves (ie such costs are usually supported by
Government subsidy);
- there is a deluge of data about tourism and its growth prospects, though
not about factors which enable its strategic value to be assessed. There is
no strategic value in an industry with large (and growing) inputs and
outputs, unless substantial value added is retained by the community. To
date there has been an uncritical emphasis on tourism's growth rates, and
foreign exchange earnings without consideration of: the debt service costs
on borrowings to earn foreign exchange; or whether the resources could have
been used more effectively employed elsewhere if Queensland had really tried
to develop its economy. Also (a) mainstream economists do not regard tourism
as a basis for economic prosperity (eg Kolson T., 'Conversation with an Ant
Economist - Our Trading Partners have it Made', Business Queensland
28/9/92). (b) Analysis of tourist industries in less developed countries
show they have less favourable than predicted impacts in terms of:
decentralisation; indigenous employment; and income distribution. Critical
review of tourism is far more important in a developed economy where there
are alternative opportunities (Aislabie etal 'Trends in Tourism Research -
An overview' in Tisdell et al, The Economics of Tourism University
of Newcastle, 1988, pp1-14). Furthermore tourism appears to suffer various
adverse social impacts. It is criticised as intrusive; noisy; often corrupt
and authoritarian; and linked with prostitution (Robinson P. 'Behind the
Neon Glow of Tourism', Sun Herald, 21/2/93; and a source of health
problems (Kennedy F., 'Tourists make Cairns Sex Bug Capital', W.Aust
14-15/8/93). The biggest single event drawcard for overseas dollars is
Sydney's Gay and Lesbian Mardi Gras (Robinson P., `Mardi Gras: Minor
Victory', Sun Herald, 6/3/94). Tourism is a suspected target for
investment of 'laundered' money by organised crime (Robinson P. 'Former NCA
Chief warns that Japan's Gangs also Invest', Age, 23/7/88 - quoting
Sir Max Bingham). Very large sums are available globally for investment (eg
$85bn pa from drugs profits in USA and Europe - Anon, 'Flushing Funny Money
into the Open', Economist, May 5, 1990, p91-92). Hawaii has been
said to have become dependent on gangster investment, and to be subject to
their dominant political influence;
- transport and distribution (whilst essential) may also not be desirable as
key growth sectors in themselves because of the case presented by Jacobs (op
cit) that cities do not prosper if they mainly act as handling centres for a
region's resources. Such functions might best support new highly productive
industries, which would provide something economically valuable to transport
and distribute. The proposal that Brisbane serve as a trade 'Gateway' for
East Australia needs to be considered from this viewpoint (eg by first
building high value trade flows to give purpose and direction to the
infrastructure rather than just providing facilities for the benefit of
those who now control Australia's trade).
Methods proposed to foster economic development lack credibility:
- there was an emphasis on 'recruitment' of industry (eg keys to wealth
creation were seen as having vision' and providing information, or as
assistance to potential investors, and for business to be welcome). SE
Queensland was said to be attractive because of: access to Asia / Pacific
markets; transport infrastructure; industrial land; and low business costs.
Attachment F indicates that industrial 'recruitment' may no longer be
international 'best practice'. Likewise proposals for 'marketing' existing
attractions is inadequate, because the economic environment is not yet
capable of supporting highly productive modern industries. In addition,
recruitment of firms only affects the economy at the margin, whist much
greater gains are available from lifting the support available to the
'mainstream' of firms;
- Australia has been sliding backwards in international competitiveness as
assessed by organisations such as the International Institute for Management
and Development, and the World Economic Forum (eg Dusevic T., 'Australia
Slipping Further Behind', Australian Financial Review, 20/6/91).
Whilst Australia has good infrastructure and reasonable human resources, it
is unattractive in terms of factors such as: international orientation;
capability of financial system; management capabilities; and science and
technology. These latter issues were not considered by the Industrial
Location and Tourism papers;
- 'technology' and value added manufacturing are said to be sectors for
attention, but no indication is given of the requirement for their success,
or how such conditions could be created. Suggested steps such as clustering
to promote productivity and creativity may help, but would not be enough.
The attractiveness of the region or of industrial sites from an
environmental viewpoint is not sufficient either. As noted previously,
technology parks succeed where the commercial and technological climate is
right. They do not create that climate;
- provision of industrial sites receives emphasis as a means to promote
industrial location, despite the past failure of such emphasis. In the
1960s, Queensland Governments first adopted industrial development as a
goal, and a study of the major obstacles revealed a key market failure in
providing land. The then Department of Industrial Development chose to
provide industrial land directly rather than to stimulate market mechanisms
to do so. As a result (a) an industrial estate program was undertaken for
decades at great cost (b) the process was affected by political pressures
and provided land in the most unlikely and unnecessary places (c) no one
really took any notice when academic studies suggested after 15 years that
the provision of industrial land did not seem to affect the decision by
firms to locate in a region, but merely affected where in the region they
would locate (Berryman J. 'Survey of Business on Queensland's Industrial
Estates', Planner, June 1981) (d) whatever was the second priority
for supporting industrial development in the 1960s never received much
attention, because resources were concentrated on industrial land (ie
essentially Queensland did not develop at all through these efforts). Though
the absence of suitable sites is a real problem, this should best be
addressed by a once off program to 'fix' the non governmental machinery
which is supposed to provide such sites, rather than by ongoing emphasis on
specific site requirements;
- cultural development is seen as a 'soft' issue which has no apparent
purpose other than recognition of cultural diversity. However, culture
refers to the ways things are done, and to the intellectual basis (ie what
people believe) which underpins this. Future prosperity and security require
real cultural development towards (say): real Asia literacy (which is much
more than just languages and customs); productivity and savings rather than
leisure and consumption; and grass roots environmental sensitivity.
The location of economic functions is envisaged to be constructively
manipulated by administrators:
- Creating Our Future envisaged that someone (Government?) is able
to create jobs in desired growth centres without reference to the
development of productive capabilities or the existence of markets. Local /
community development can generate enterprises and employment, yet
practitioners usually lack the knowledge and mandate to deal with other than
marginal and low productivity ventures;
- regional and subregional growth strategies were suggested to be framed by
government agencies, yet they are not in touch with the main driving forces
of an economy (ie market demand);
- advisory committees are supposed to assess regionally significant
industries. Yet competition is the only way in which such priorities can
realistically and safely be set (because of the lack of information to 'pick
winners', and the risk of capture by interest groups).