Looking Deeper
Before attempting to evaluate the implications of this situation, there is a
need to consider other background information concerning:
National Electricity Market
Because the implications for electricity GOCs of competing in a national electricity market
(NEM) do not seem to have been publicly considered in discussing Queensland's
network development failure, the NEM's implications will be outlined first.
Background: A
NEM
was established in 1998 as part of a (1992) National Competition Policy (NCP) whose
goal (broadly) was to create incentive for improved performance by removing
regulatory obstacles to competition and thus to improve the productivity and
international competitiveness of Australian businesses. The latter was in turn
a component of a 1980s' package of reforms (including financial deregulation
and tariff reform) to liberalize markets hopefully to reduce problems in
Australia's economy (eg a long term decline in Australia's relative income
levels by international standards was expected to be halted / reversed if resources were
allocated to suit customer demand rather than political preferences).
The NEM is significant in relation to Queensland's electricity network
development failure because:
First, the NEM does not seem to be working well - and electricity
industry organization in NSW and Queensland has been described as part of the
problem.
For example:
- Australia's national electricity market has been seen to need reform [1].
- NSW and Queensland are distorting NEM [1]
- and could impede investment. State ownership of power assets undermines
confidence that decisions will be made in interests of consumers. There is a
conflict of interest between states as owners and regulators. Victoria
suffers under-investment because governments in NSW and Queensland protect
their market share. [1]
- gains from NEM in terms of reduced prices have not come - and ministers
have taken control from bureaucrats because the politically difficult
outcomes. Competition might have produced better results without complex NEM
machinery [1].
- power users are concerned about the risk of large energy cost
increases with adverse effects on investment [1]
- Concentration of generation capacity in a few hands is seen to be
driving up national power costs [1]
- private investment is held back by complex regulation and a lack of
physical interconnection [1].
- Gas and electricity may be over-regulated by many state regimes [1]
- it is of concern that an explosion which disrupted the NSW electricity system appeared to have most adverse
effects in Queensland [1]
Moreover the Queensland Government's decision not to extend competition to retail consumers
(ie households) illustrates the difficulty in creating a NEM and has been
controversial because (a) the effect is to conceal a hidden subsidy which SEQ consumers
provide for those in rural areas - which would otherwise have to be paid
directly by Treasury at taxpayers expense and (b) the Government's assumption that there
would be no potential economic gains from introducing competition seems overly
simplistic (see
Queensland's
Rejection of Retail Electricity Competition).
Second one suggested solution to problems in the NEM would involve
creating a national electricity regulator [1,
2,
3], and
the governance arrangements for Queensland's GOCs would probably need radical
reform if an effective NEM were created and the state became simply a market
competitor rather than also being the regulator - because those arrangements do not at
present allow GOCs to cope with real competition (see below).
It can be noted in passing that:
- Australia is not unique in having
difficulties organizing an electricity market as in the US de-regulation was
variously seen to have resulted in either over-capacity and
investor losses when demand stalled [1]
or under-investment [1].
Extreme weather conditions led to 1 in 100 year demand, which no one found it
profitable to install capacity to service [1];
and
- there are reasons to suspect that (a) there are limitations in any assumption
that market liberalization is an adequate way of dealing with the
challenge of competitiveness (see
Defects in
Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes) and (b) that the application of
business-like methods is an inadequate way of thinking about the delivery of
public goods and services (see
Governing is not
just running a large business).
Effective Governance of Queensland's Electricity Industry
Government owned electricity undertakings, as for many other major government undertakings, have been re-organized over the past 15 year on a corporatisation
model - which involved establishing separate legal entities that attempt to
operate on a business-like basis (ie focusing on financial returns to guide
investment and service decisions, rather than on the policies of elected
government which had guided such decision under the earlier Statutory Authority
model). The role of Ministers shifted from providing policy directions to (a)
acting as shareholders (b) considering the GOC's proposals and (c) having the
option to achieve public interest goals through direct budgetary commitments
(ie Community Service Obligations).
Corporatisation was initially motivated by a Treasury desire to increase
financial returns to government from business undertakings (eg by improving
efficiency) and subsequently by the National Competition Policy requirement for
competitive service delivery. Restructuring of Queensland's electricity
industry followed 1996 recommendations by the Electricity Industry Structure
Task Force.
However there were problems in corporatisation, as:
- maximizing public revenues from GOCs (eg by simply cutting costs) is not
the same as, and is likely to be inconsistent with, maximizing economic
benefits (by forcing down product prices through competition and requiring
GOCs to innovate to increase their revenues);
- the Electricity Industry Structure Task Force seemed to base its
evaluation on micro-economic principles such as those underpinning NCP -
rather than on the requirements for corporatised GOCs to operate successfully
in a competitive environment;
- it is intrinsically impossible for GOCs ever to be competitively neutral
with private firms because the latter can focus on the needs of their
customers, while GOCs are also always bound to conform with interest group
pressures (even if only by informal pressure and government control over
appointments to boards of directors) - see
Note 76 on Queensland's Challenge
and note (by way of example) that electricity GOCs were to have been used
as a policy tool to subsidize the development of a gas industry (see
Note 52). Thus in any truly
competitive environment, GOCs must deliver losses to their government
shareholders - as has been the common experience of 'nationalized industries'
to which GOCs are equivalent;
- the Queensland Treasury took the lead nationally in establishing
techniques for assessing the performance of GOCs in terms of real rate of
return on capital; while at the same time
- a 1997 literature survey by the present author showed evidence that significant adjustments were occurring in international best practices
in response to competition in electricity industries but that these did not seem to be
occurring in Queensland (eg more sophisticated costing, new approaches to
capital budgeting, major changes in economic evaluation of power generation,
and new methods for management and innovation);
Various observers have suggested that there are problems in Queensland's electricity
industry.
For example:
- Queensland's electricity industry was seen to be in disarray with:
- a
policy vacuum;
- inability to control retailers (eg in deals being done,
ambitions to become generators or operate nationally);
- varying styles of
generators (ie state owned, partly privatized, fully private);
- uncertainty
about retail competition;
- dysfunctional outcomes of competition between Energex and Ergon (where
the former labeled the latter's management as hopeless);
- losses
from politically inspired energy trading; and
- pressure for privatization
which would affect government budget. [1]
- Queensland's largest private generator argued [perhaps with a hidden
agenda] that further investment in Queensland was unlikely due to government
interference [1]
- problems (kickbacks) were seen to exist in Ergon's tendering process [1]
- a need was seen to privatize the electricity industry for it to cope with
interstate and international competition - noting Austa's losses on a failed
Chinese venture [1]. Queensland's
Commission of Audit had recommended that the industry be privatized;
- tariffs do not reflect the real cost of electricity - especially in peak
periods [1].
- the possibility of inadequate electricity supplies was suggested in 2003
[1]. Widespread installation of air-conditioners
was one reason
identified for network inadequacy [1,
2]
- there are uncertainties about how to deliver power. Though the system has
been corporatised over the past decade, Energex was out of touch with its
customer base. There are difficult technical questions about (a) how to
upgrade the network (b) fixed tariffs and city - country subsidies (c) peak
power pricing (d) restrictions in housing codes on electricity use in new
houses (e) retail competition. [1]
It is in this context it should be noted that:
- various observers suggested (see above) that the network
development failure required general reform of GOCs or subjecting their
boards to commercial rather than political accountability.
- the State Government made a political commitment to 'fix' the network deficiency
without regard to cost [1],
and the first move by new energy minister was to block Energex's plan for
dealing with crisis while proposing a major shake-up [1]
- and this will:
- further undermine the future ability of electricity GOCs to make
investment / service decisions on the commercial basis which is essential
in a competitive environment. While the 'fix' was partly expressed as regulations (eg penalties for poor standards)
which would be consistent with a market model, the
goals were determined politically not commercially and it is government
money which will drive changes;
- (possibly) require that either Queensland tries to opt out of the competitive
national electricity market, or that Queensland's electricity GOCs be
privatized;
- the Premier then in turn over-ruled his new energy minister's proposal to
allow the chief executives of Energex and Ergon brief the Opposition on
proposed system development on the grounds that this would involve 'public
servants' in a political slanging match [1]
[Comment: it seems inappropriate to treat such chief executives a
'public servants' who are to be uninvolved in political controversy if their
role is like the chief executive of a company operating in a competitive
market];
- one observer suggested that general reform of governance arrangements of Australia's GOCs was needed [1];
- an ex-chairman of another GOC (the Queensland Investment Corporation) suggested that interference by ministers who did not
understand fund management contributed to its poor financial results at one
stage [1];
Other governance concerns associated with the narrow terms of reference of
the Independent Panel which reviewed Queensland's electricity network are also
suggested below.
To promote effective governance there is perhaps also a need to consider carefully the
conflicts of interest that can arise where private firms are both key
technical advisers
to governments and
potential beneficiaries of valuable government contracts, noting:
- the parallels between
the general concept of public private partnerships for
infrastructure in Australia and the US 'military industrial complex' and the
Japanese 'construction state' in both of which
systemic abuses are often seen to exist because of such conflicts;
- the very large fees that might be obtained from (say) organizing the
privatization of Queensland's electricity industry by firms with good
relationships with the government. [It can be noted that one
expert seems to be recommending privatization as a necessary solution to the
problem of regulatory complexity [1]
].
The conflicts which can arise where private firms are both key technical
advisers and prospective contractors to government are similar to those
outlined below that have arisen as purely political accountability has
displaced professional accountability in the Public Service.
Technical Competence
Queensland's Premier reportedly defended his colleges in relation to the
electricity network crisis by arguing that no one can anticipate every
departmental problem, and that a good government will seek to identify and fix
problems that arise [1].
However because governments can not anticipate every departmental
problem it is essential that they have professionally skilled
support (both in the Public Service and in their business undertakings) to
attend competently to issues that are not politically foreseeable. Likewise,
while good government certainly requires a willingness to identify and fix
problems, it is even more important to genuinely seek competent support to
minimize the number of problems that do arise (as the present author first
argued in a submission to the ALP's election
review committee after the 1995 defeat of the Goss administration).
Unfortunately, irrespective of whether cronyism may have been a factor in making board
appointments in electricity GOCs as various observers
suggested, it is a fact that:
Public
administration
failures
seem to have emerged in many areas as a result (ie administrative
dysfunctions are by no means limited to electricity supply). And the potential
for this to continue is illustrated by:
- the establishment of an
Implementation Unit in the Premier's Department which will reportedly develop a
'hit list' of 50-100 top political priorities so as to ensure that these are
achieved. Relying on rigid enforcement of political edicts will create the risk that 'the wheels
could fall off' virtually anything / everything else (see
Queensland's
'Administrative Desperation' Unit);
- the likelihood that an attempt to 'fix' administrative failures in
dealing with child protection will provide little more than a cosmetic
cover-up - because (amongst other things) the systemic failures
which emerged in the Families Department were merely an extreme case of
problems that were (and remain) endemic in the Public
Service as a whole, and focusing on the few items in a reform 'blue-print'
can lead to a myopic loss of focus on other important issues (see
Review of CMC's Child
Protection Proposals)
There is no 'quick fix' for a Public Service whose knowledge and
skills have run-down any more than there is for a workforce
lacking the skills to re-develop the electricity network (see above)
Relationship with Public Financing
Many observers have suggested that (excess) dividend
payments to government have been a key factor in the inability of electricity
GOCs to develop their networks, while others have denied this.
However even more important is that:
- electricity GOCs have been key sources of support for Queensland's
budget bottom line. Years before there was concern about drawing excessive
dividends, it appeared that the assets of electricity GOCs were run down by requiring them to increase debts so as to
pay large dividends - see Note 53
and Note 73 on Queensland's
Challenge, and note that other observers suggested that government has seen electricity utilities as a cash cow [1];
- running down GOC assets appeared to support a very high rate of capital
investment which Queensland is now expected to maintain / increase;
- the state government appears to be under intense financial pressure if
the effect of revenue gains from a property boom is discounted (see
Growing Pressure for Tax Increases)
and any substantial reduction in net payments from the electricity industry,
which now appears likely, will increase that pressure. Net payments from
electricity industry might reduce because of:
- smaller dividends;
- a need for capital injections (which might be very large [1]); and
- a need for community-service-obligation payments from Treasury to rural
consumers to maintain uniform tariffs if retail competition is introduced and
consumers in SE Queensland can no longer be forced to pay a hidden subsidy (see
Queensland's
Rejection of Retail Electricity Competition);
Role of the Independent Panel
Unfortunately the work of the Independent Panel which reviewed Queensland's
electricity network was not without defects.
The Panel chairman made a speech downplaying the significance of problems in the electricity
networks by presenting them mainly as consequences of regulatory failure [1] - a
situation
which some in the the media saw as embroiling him in the controversy [1].
Given the other widely-perceived problems in Queensland's electricity
industry outlined in the present document, his speech made the Panel's focus
on regulatory aspects seem inadequate as an assessment of problems in the
electricity networks.
The problem may well be that the Panel operated under
terms of reference which
required them to deal only with government's
regulatory role and internal procedures in the electricity companies, and this
prevented attention being given to critical matters related to
Government's role as owner of the electricity companies. The latter role, it
can be noted:
- gave the Government ultimate control of the service providers (as well as
regulating them); and
- led to the complex relationship between the electricity industry and
State public finances.
The Panel did not (as far as the present author is aware) highlight this
apparently serious defect in its terms of reference.
|