Basic
Defects
|
A. Problems in the Basic PPP Model - Comments Based on
Partnerships Victoria (PV)
Details of Partnerships Victoria (PV) are available
on the web.
"Partnerships Victoria is concerned mainly with the establishment of
partnerships for public infrastructure and related ancillary services".
MoreSchools may join the growing list of of services gaining
private funding (Cornell A. 'Regulators not in the real world',
Financial Review, 25/2/02)
The Goal
The goals for PV (and the criteria for public benefit tests) were
suggested to relate to equity. PV involves a means for private sector
contracting for delivery of public infrastructure services.
The intent of PV and PPPs generally is to increasing efficiency in
service delivery.
For example: The ability that PPPs provides to undertake integrated
life-cycle planning is likely to deliver real cost savings (Gray J. 'Going private a $20bn shake up',
Australian, 11/2/02).
Transferring risk to the private sector is another way in which costs may
be reduced.
For example: NSW, Queensland and Victorian labor governments are
pushing PPPs. These are seen as either an expensive attempt to
privatize public services or as a way to enhance the quality of social
infrastructure that delivers value for money to taxpayers. There are
many different PPP models. Often these can deliver improved facilities
much faster than the public sector (with its competing capital demands)
can do. It is unrealistic to expect the private sector to offer
innovations whilst competing against public providers. The advantage of
PPPs is risk transfer - because the public sector will always be
cheaper if cost of funds is the only criterion. But when cost
over-runs, maintenance problems, unavailable facilities are factored in
- the balance tips. Though PPPs give value for money, they usually
require new government revenue to service the annual costs. PPPs should
not be seen in terms of privatization (Wilde M. (Deloitte Touche Ross)
'PPPs are about transferring risk', Financial Review, 12/4/02)
An Overview: Australia has long been a recipient of things
British. Now it is the PPP concept. The practice -
called private finance initiatives (PFI) in the UK has been used before -
but is now becoming widely accepted. PPP can refer to many different
things - contractual outsourcing; private financing; or full
privatization. Australian's main PPP advocate (Dennis O'Neill of the
Australian Council for Infrastructure and Development) says that
Australia's experience has been tempered by UK experience - noting
Partnerships Victoria and Working with Government NSW.
Governments are seeking value for money. Governments have sought to define
more specifically what they want in terms of policy and outcomes. The
states are taking the lead, because of their primary responsibility for
infrastructure delivery. The most important reasons for government to
include the private sector are the application of capital, efficiency and
speed. Efficiency gains of 15-20% (and similar speed gains) can be
achieved. There is more scope for innovation the earlier one comes to the
market, and it is possible to go forward with much simpler specifications.
There are also maintenance side benefits (and projects tend to involve
this). Governments have a fixed division between capital and maintenance,
and PPPs allow this to be removed. There is a lot of commonality around
Australia, which avoid self-defeating complexity. Politics can be a
barrier to PPPs - and even though PPPs are becoming more popular, getting
widespread community support is a challenge. There is concern about who
supplies the service - and PPP arrangements can be quite complex. Most
opposition comes from those with an ideological view that only government
should provide infrastructure - and this raises issues as privatization is
part of the spectrum. But PPPs are not just are not just back-door
privatization. Access to capital is also an issue. Governments do not want
to borrow so as to keep their AAA ratings. PPPs are seen as a solution.
Integrated schools, public transport and commercial space will bring
integrated property opportunities. There is also a need for more
integrated transport hubs. There can be an alliance between property and
infrastructure developers - given political leadership. Eventually
PPPs will be the preferred method for infrastructure delivery - at present
it is only about 15% because community acceptance is the major barrier.
This won't make the world perfect, just better, as some projects will
always fail. The Australian Council for Infrastructure and Development
studied public perceptions - which showed strong acceptance of the PPP
concept for new infrastructure - but concern about 'privatization by
stealth'. And support is increasing. Another major surge in infrastructure
projects around Australia will be needed over the next 5 years - and state
governments want private finance for most of this, though there is
uncertainty about how much they will fund. Private funding has fallen off
- partly due to changes in tax rules. Governments will need to provide
greater subsidies. (Hatcher Nigel. 'Setting off on the PPP road',
Property Australia, May
2002)
There is nothing new about the private sector contracting to provide discrete
elements of public goods and services. What seems to be different
about PPPs is that they seek private involvement in managing particular
services as a whole, and in the provision of finance.
Economic Benefits
Though there is probably a potential for such cost savings, the economic
impact of PV may be quite small because:
- the anticipated cost savings may be hard to realize
(as discussed below) because of the
difficulties of effective contract management;
- one source of efficiency from private service delivery is likely to be
expected from flexible industrial relations. [In fact some might
(undesirably) hope that cost savings from private delivery can be associated
with simply paying employees less].
- the overview of PV said nothing about industrial relations
arrangements, and it is likely that the required flexibility will be
prevented by legislation;
- unions in Queensland and WA have expressed concerns about PPPs, and
have sought an extension of time for making submissions in relation to
Queensland's PPP proposal. Though business suggested that confidence would
be dented if government gave way to unions, and the Premier argued that
PPPs are essential to allow Queensland to maintain a high rate of capital
spending without raising taxes, union leaders have branded PPPs as
'privatization by stealth' (Emerson S. 'Showdown looms on partnership
deadline', Australian, 18-19/5/02)
- cost saving is quite different to raising economic productivity. The
latter requires enterprising leadership in the development and operation of
services.
Raising economic productivity (ie achieving high economic
value-added either in infrastructure operations or related sectors)
depends mainly on an operator's market focus and on its flexibility to
follow the market - and only to a small degree on production
efficiency. This arises because, in a competitive environment, other
producers quickly copy any efficiency gains and prices are bid down to
the lowered production costs. The economic gains that result from
privatizing Brisbane airport (for example) have more to do with the
operator's commercial orientation, than with their 'efficiency'.
Certainly sustainable competitive advantages may come from a high rate
of gain in efficiency (but this is a 'flexibility of work practices'
issue - rather than due to static 'efficiency').
Under PV, government is responsible for identifying and
researching needs, and then tightly specifying and controlling the
outputs. Thus a real market focus and flexibility (and significantly
raised economic productivity) can not be gained. Similarly where (as
under PV) infrastructure decisions are based on governmental
benefit / cost analysis it is only possible to 'measure' the obvious
benefits, without scope to raise them through building synergy with
other interests - which could be a major potential contribution if the
private sector can take the initiative.
Public Financing Benefits?
PPPs are seen by some as a way to increase the
financial resources available so as to allow more services to be provided and
sooner.
However this is a somewhat doubtful benefit for reasons outlined in
Section C.
It has also been suggested that, on some occasions
(such as where a private infrastructure element competes directly with a 'free'
/ publicly funded service, public sector subsidies are the only way to make the
the private investment profitable [1].
This creates clear difficulties in an environment in which (a) the PPP process
has been seen to result in some cases in large private profits at public
expense and (b) non-transparent incentives have been used to encourage public
support for particular private infrastructure investments.
Criticism and Defense
PV seems to be based on techniques developed and extensively used
by the Blair Government in the UK - which (in contrast to Australia) had a
tradition of private involvement in public services until World War II, and a
very strong reliance on privately-provided public services until the reforms in
the 1850s which created a professional Civil Service.
The UK government is rewriting the text book on social democratic
politics - especially through private provision of public services
involving PPPs rather than through privatization or outsourcing. In
Australia and USA much attention has been given to UK government
intervention in Railtrack - but this is a minor issue and the
government is pressing ahead in areas such as education, health and
many other areas. Reasons for the lesser involvement by Labor
Governments in the Australian states may include: (a) different
party composition - where leading liberals are in UK Labor - and
differences in the union movement where public sector unions also
cover private sector members (b) pragmatic leadership which sees
the problem from the viewpoint of consumers rather than producers
(c) external pressures such as fiscal stress and EU rules
prescribing competition between health systems - say (d) public
opinion - where, in health, there is little enthusiasm for the
public system (e) a traditional institutional reliance on private
institutions in delivering public services until WWII. Even the
Northcote Trevelyan report which laid the foundation for the UK
civil service was based on a private company - the East India
Company. Australia tends to follow the UK's lead - but by the time
Australia's systems were established the trend towards
municipalisation and nationalization was already well under way.
However there also also Australian precedents to draw upon - in
private tollways and private schooling (Sturgess G. 'Private Risk,
Public Service', Centre for
Independent Studies, Autumn 2002)
The effectiveness of those techniques has been subjected to a great deal of
criticism.
For example: comments on Third Way politics
in the UK
(and on the UK model) indicates a
general dissatisfaction with government performance in the UK
(increasingly in relation to PPPs), and that electoral support seems to be
maintained mainly because no opposition party is seen to have any policy
proposals that would be better. And Barry Jones' discussion of
the ALP's Knowledge Nation Task Force (Jones B. 'Can we make Australia a
Knowledge Nation?', Address at Macquarie University, 27/4/01) suggested
that UK public administration was in serious difficulties with crises in
privatized rail systems, mad cow disease, foot and mouth disease all seen
to be due to the hollowing out of expertise, the increase in simple
'management' and a decline in effective accountability.
Criticism (and defense) of PPP arrangements has also arisen in Australia.
Examples of debate:
- PPPs cause concern - especially in NSW.
Governments have (a) agreed to un-commercial terms that have imposed
high costs on taxpayers (b) turned user fees into general taxes (c)
adopted inconsistent policies in different cities regarding tolls or
public funding of similar infrastructure (d) and entered into lease
arrangements for buildings that make government responsible for
upgrading the building (Harris T. 'Infrastructure's hard road',
Financial Review, 29/1/02)
- PV's Public Sector comparator (to determine whether it is
better to go for private or public sector provision) has been described
as complex (Gray J. 'Going private a $20bn shake
up', Australian, 11/2/02).
- Enron was based on 3 principles (a) being asset light - rather than
owing assets it used contracts with partners (b) financial innovation
based on the view that the private sector would produce better results
than public sector (c) shifting debts off-balance-sheet to secure a
good credit rating. Australian governments have also been selling
public assets (to reduce public debts) and shifting their obligations
off-balance-sheet - by renting. Sometimes this provides flexibility -
but sometimes government is the only logical user. There would be few
problems in Commonwealth sale and lease-back arrangements if these were
treated as borrowings - ie capitalized onto the balance sheet.
Partnerships Victoria is similar - where concerns exist about the
public sector 'comparator'. In UK proposals for private finance for
upgrading Underground showed twice the cost - yet 2 of 3 analysts
signed off on this as constituting value for money (Quiggin J. 'Enron's
Australian cousin' Financial Review, 28/2/02)
- Following UK examples, many Australian governments are considering
'private financing initiatives' (known in Australia as PPPs) under
which private enterprises build, own operate physical infrastructure.
Such initiatives have been widely adopted in transport, and are being
extended to social infrastructure (eg schools and hospitals) - where
often private owner manages the building while public sector provides
the services. Many early initiatives have been criticized, and shown to
have reduced net worth of public sector. The superficial appeal of
reducing public debt has been shown as illusory. Advocates claim that
problems have been overcome by appropriate allocation of risk. Before
1980s infrastructure tended to be owned by public sector and
constructed by private sector under competitive tendering. As concerns
about budget deficits mounted, devises were used to reduce 'debt
burden'. BOOT schemes were particularly popular (under which private
sector built facility, operated on user-pays basis and then transfers
to public sector. This approach has been criticized (eg by EPAC
Infrastructure Task Force, Industry Commission) because (a) apparent
reduction in debt is illusory (b) risk is misallocated when used for
transport because real risk is in planning of network as a whole rather
than in constructing project - but private constructor gains the
premium return from tolls. Sale and leaseback deals have also been used
- most particularly by Commonwealth Department of Finance which has
been prepared to pay up to a 15% return - a practice which the Audit
Office ascribed to a misunderstanding of the Capital Asset Pricing
Model. While these arrangements appear to reduce public debt this is
illusory - and there is no reduced risk born by public sector. There is
a claim that private providers enjoy a 20% cost advantage, but there is
a need here to distinguish between real cost advantages and costs
transferred to others in society (eg hidden subsidies, or paying lower
wages). In the UK public assets were often sold at substantial
discounts in the 1980s. This approach was rejected by Blair Government
in 1997 - and adopted a new value-for-money goal, which AG and
Parliamentary reports suggest has not yet been demonstrated. Also many
PFI infrastructure service providers has performed badly in the UK.
There are two problems with the idea that public debt problems can be
solved by private infrastructure investment (a) often such deals have
government guaranteed payments with identical fiscal and economic
effects to repaying public debts (b) public debt should not, in itself,
be a policy target - as the key issue is net public sector worth (an
issue highlighted by accrual accounting in Australia). In Australia
government reduced its debts by selling Telstra shares for less than
they were worth - thus also reducing its net worth. Allocation and
management of risk is of central importance - which was initially
ignored, and now (eg in Partnerships Victoria) gains a lot of
attention. Risk should be born where there is only one party involved,
by that party. A major problem arises in working out the transfer of
financial risk associated with project ownership. Usually the rate of
discount applied to public investments has been the bond rate - but
PFIs are usually evaluated on the assumption that the cost of risk to
government must be as great as for private sector. A straightforward
application of risk management principles suggests that infrastructure
should be publicly financed, and privately constructed. That PFI
analyses reach different conclusions is attributable to unproven
ideological assumptions. (Quiggin
J. 'Private financing of public infrastructure', Dissent,
Autumn / Winter 2002)
- PPPs are popular because governments are bowing to business
pressure to get onto the government teat. UK Government policy was
recently criticized in Economist - which argued that government
can't really transfer risk to the private sector because government
can't afford to let projects fail. Also PPPs do not provide more
finance - as they merely substitute long term contractual obligations
for debt repayment (Sheil C. 'Significant appeal of PPPs falling
apart', FR, 24/5/02)
- PPPs are supposed to allow state planning to
be combined with privatization, and better manage risk. Though they are
now being widely embraced, one should read the fine print. PPPs allow
the logjam of public funds to be broken. PPPs are not new - they have
often been used for motorways. 40% of infrastructure in developing
countries is built this way. But negotiation of the contract is the key
issue. In UK taxpayers have been hit as private companies run rings
around government sponsors in negotiations. In some cases, deal
was agreed on basis of one source of funding with private sector then
arranging cheaper financing so that government paid too much.
Skepticism arises in Queensland from financial failure of proto-PPPs (eg
airport rail link) which government rescued. Similarly governments
simply can't afford to let hospitals fail. The key to PPPs is that
there be a clear transfer of risk to the private sector - without
assuming that government will step in when problems arise (Marris S.
'Nice public work - if you can get it', Australian, 17/6/02)
- The Beattie Government faces a show-down with the unions over PPPs
- which the QCU has not treated as a stand-alone issue but as linked to
Queensland's 'low tax' mantra. QCU suggested that guidelines throw up
unanswerable questions about project failures which leaves risk with
government, and budgetary constraints on future governments. Government
policy that rejected tax rises was seen as irresponsible. QCU official
response says unions are fundamentally opposed to PPPs. Other areas of
concern include: risk to public sector wages; low threshold; lack of
scrutiny due to commercial confidentiality; escalation of service
costs; community inability to appeal PPP decisions. Commitments reduce
flexibility of future governments. The public will accept the need for
higher taxes if they can see benefits (Owen R 'PPP plan throws fuel on
union fire', CM, 31/7/02)
- The Queensland Government has released draft PPP guidelines. These
comments deal with the issue from a QCU viewpoint, without considering
all aspects, and have relied on documents provided by government and a
few other sources. The QCU is opposed private involvement in
infrastructure with a $30m threshold, and believes that much of the
evidence about the public benefit of PPPs is negative, and that risks
remain with government. The reference material shows that projects
subject to PPPs could have been delivered by the public sector - and UK
cases suggest they could often have delivered at a lower cost - because
government is able to borrow more cheaply. The public may benefit from
earlier provision using private funds, but government faces a risk of
then having to meet unbudgeted costs if the firms abandon the project.
Public benefits can also be reduced where charges are applied to
previously free services. The private sector benefits from PPPs though
gaining access to new revenue sources. Private involvement in
infrastructure makes it harder to assess value-for-money. The $30m
threshold indicates that government wants private infrastructure
involvement to be much greater than in the past. Various projects have
been proposed for PPPs without following the process required by the
guidelines, or the application of a Public Sector comparator. The scope
that exists for unsolicited project proposals suggests that the private
sector could bid for existing work, where it could do so more cheaply.
This has implications for job security, increased user-pays regimes and
the extent of public ownership of assets. These is a potential conflict
of interest between private firms orientation to shareholders, and
government's concern with serving the public. Where a private firm
walks away from a project, government has all the risk (eg debts and
the need to provide services) - which has political consequences.
Government may be faced with unfunded liabilities. Private partners
have great bargaining power with government once projects have started
- and governments have often been forced to pay heavily when problems
arise. Where a service is essential, government must continue it even
if a private partner is in breach of obligations. Failures can arise
even where huge transnational firms are involved. PPPs which require
long term commitments, create budget inflexibility. Shifting risk to
the private sector is a major part of the rationale for PPPs. However,
in reality, government retains all the risk if the private partner
fails - and this risk is not mentioned in the documents. The risk to
public sector employees of unsolicited project proposals is also not
mentioned. In the UK, major savings in prison administration through a
PPP followed from reducing wages and conditions. Shifting industrial
relations responsibility to the private sector could: transfer secure
public sector jobs to the private sector; reduce wages and conditions;
end government responsibilities for providing secure employment; result
in delays. ('PPPs: Queensland Council of Unions Response to Draft
Framework Document', 2002)
- In the UK, private financing of public facilities is well
established - but is not necessarily well accepted. Unions rolled the
Government at a Labor Party congress - seeking an audit of the effect
of PPPs on pay rates, and on concealment of public debt. Unions have
argued that PPPs have higher borrowing costs, higher set up costs and
higher running costs.. The Blair Government is however convinced. UK
officials argue that PPPs deliver benefits because public sector can
define desired outputs and leave it to the private sector to work out
how. It is however hard to compare different ways of project delivery.
But infrastructure had been crumbling under traditional policies.
Australian Council for Infrastructure Development argues that Danish
study of conventionally organized road projects showed a 20-40% cost
blow-out - because of incentives to give an initial under-estimate.
Australian Government views PPPs as some sort of 'Enron' device for
concealing profits. In UK investor returns from new PPPs are falling
(Taylor L. 'Strange bedfellows', FR, 4/10/02)
-
Federal revenue minister has indicated changes in tax treatment of PPPs - by distinguishing between
genuine leases and those that are mere tax dodges. Tax laws deny deductions to private firms when
assets are leased by state governments. Without this sub-national governments could scam the
Commonwealth by contrived leases to transfer to private firms the deductions that states can't use
because they do not pay tax. A criticism of PPPs is that they are contrivances to shift public debt off
balance sheet. With states notionally committed to demonstrating value-for-money, pro-privatisation
groups have attacked this by claiming (a) differences in financing costs are compensated by greater
efficiencies - but can't prove this (b) asserting that there is no difference between
public and private
financing costs. The minister has promised to change the test for whether PPPs are real or contrived.
(Sheil C., 'Coonans next can of worms: PPPs', FR, 6/12/02).
-
PPPs do not actually increase the amount of money available for
infrastructure - but give a false impression that the public does not have a
debt. Specific defects in infrastructure guidelines are also suggested (Quiggan
J., 'Financing Infrastructure
for Queensland', 30/3/03)
-
Claims from Macquarie Infrastructure Group officer about its ability to unilaterally set changes
for toll road in UK (which users had no alternative to paying) have caused controversy (Shand A
and Taylor L 'Road rage', FR, 17-18/5/03)
-
PPPs have been criticised by both Allen Consulting Group, and by union backed reform from
Strategic Economics, Paying for Private Profit. PPPs are seen as:
potentially expensive, inefficient,
inflexible and not necessarily in community interest. There is not yet seen to be adequate regime of
contestability, accountability and transparency around PPP industry. ACTU argued that PPPs were
arrangements to keep projects off budget. Recent report suggested that PPPs are plagued by
escalating costs, conflict, high consultancy fees, poor services and secrecy. It refutes 'myths' about PPPs that they:
reduce call on public funds; accelerate infrastructure provision; reduce public risk;
and enhance accountability. Allen Consulting found that case for most obvious alternative to PPPs
(government debt) is strong. (Sheil C 'The shine has come off PPPs', FR, 21/11/03)
-
PPPs have only a small niche role to play - because of their complexity [1]
-
poorly managed PPPs have been seen to create a 'master-slave' relationship[
between government and private sector [1]
-
UK experience shows that PPPs should be avoided as an infrastructure funding
model. Problems have emerged for hospitals because it has been impossible to
specify required service standards. Also higher costs have been imposed on
public sector for roads, transport and hospital services [1]
-
Brisbane City Council has proposed that various services be provided through
PPPs, while others have warned that this is a cargo cult [1]
-
the complexities which contractors face in dealing with PPPs makes the whole
exercise so complex, expensive and risky that many may be unwilling to
participate in future [1]
-
a debate emerged about the appropriateness of the Brisbane City Council's
proposal to use a PPP option for a tunnel project [1]
-
the use of PPPs for development of Sydney's transport system has given rise
to heated public controversy. For example:
-
congestion on one of Sydney's busiest roads might have been improved for $130m - instead of
building the $1.1bn Lane Cove tunnel [1]
;
- surface traffic has been
deliberately distorted to force traffic into tunnels to make them
profitable [1,
2,
3];
-
Large taxpayer subsidies are provided to make infrastructure projects
profitable [1,
2]. Moreover with PPPs
private sector can gain large profits, but government must provide subsidies when things go wrong
(eg in Melbourne's rail system) [1]
;
-
Sydney drivers are upset about the number of
tolls they have to pay (contrary to government promises), and have avoided a
contentious new tunnel [1,
2].
-
concerns have been expressed that private firms /
investment banks are proving too smart for government negotiators - resulting
in the transfer of monopoly profits (but no risk) to those firms [1]
Alternative is design-construct-maintain
arrangement which allows government to borrow at lower
rates. User pays proposals should be assessed on user
charges - not most payment to government. Projects should not be force fed, and
there should be no guarantees. [1]
- PPPs will never
account for more than 10-11% of infrastructure spending - and Australia faces substantial need
for additional spending (eg using government bonds). [1]
-
Pressure has been applied for governments to
assume more of the risk that their demand estimates may not be realistic in
new PPP regime (Hutton J etal 'King calls for PPP revamp, AFR, 12/3/09)
There are also suggestions that perceived problems are exaggerated.
For example: In Australia state governments have often lost
when PPP infrastructure schemes have failed. But in the UK companies
have also been hit. The transfer of risk can lead to private losses
- due to robust contracts and payment mechanisms. Both sectors in
the UK believe that transfer of risk has been fair. Public
comments on PPPs is generally unfavourable - blaming them for poor
service delivery. However stakeholders believe that they deliver
high quality facilities on budget. PPPs have brought benefits to the
public sector in terms of better procurement disciplines, commercial
skill; and help in refinancing (Allen L. 'Contracts blamed for
building partnership losses', Financial Review, 22/2/02)
Openness and candor are needed to make PPPs work - noting the
desire to extend this from projects like road into social
infrastructure areas (eg schools, hospitals). There have been bad
experiences where projects are arranged on the basis of lowest
costs, and so there is a negative public attitude. The private
sector is not always better paced to deliver projects - and there
are many examples which have proven the critics right.
However the negative attitude is often compounded by
misunderstanding of culture and motives. The PPP model is about
what works - to combine what the public and private sector each do
best. Public sector's suspicions about profits creates huge
barriers to real partnership. This can be overcome by shared goals
(Banks B. 'Openness, candor needed to make PPPs work', FR,
10/5/02). Christopher Sheil ('Coonan's next can of worms: PPPs') is no student of tax, and lacks
transactional experience. Australia is a large country with a small population that expects modern
infrastructure. Australia has a shrinking tax base - due to international competition. Funding for
capital expenditure lags, so a shift towards user-pay emerges. States can't maintain services and
infrastructure without PPPs. PPPs are quite transparent - and Sheil's knowledge of their balance
sheet treatment is years behind policy debate. Rating agencies count state liabilities off balance sheet
as if they were state debt. The Assistant Treasurers' proposed amendments have nothing to do with
treatment of PPP debt. PPPs are not privatisation. PPPs enhance infrastructure quality - and it is
just ignorant to assert that public debt is always cheaper - as state treasuries never factor in cost
overruns and slow delivery. Private capital costs more-or-less the true risk-weighted cost of public
debt. Government budget processes need overhauling to accommodate modern asset-management
practices - whereby PPP projects may be better value for the taxpayer, even if not cheaper. It is
nonsense to suggest that states retain all residual risks from these projects (consider Brisbane Airtrain). Current tax provisions related to private infrastructure investment are draconian - and
meeting those requirements consumes huge efforts and inhibits investments. Infrastructure investors
continue to face uncertainty - and Australia is seen as an investment jurisdiction to be regarded with
suspicion. (McBride L. 'Public-private projects are the answer', FR, 13/12/02).
There has been emerging focus on how governments meet the need for investment in economic,
social and environmental infrastructure. Christoper Sheil's article (AFR, 21/11/03)
incorrectly asserted that Allen Consulting's Funding Urban Infrastructure gave the thumbs down to PPPs in
examining the merits of public debts / PPPs in financing infrastructure. This concluded that there
were large costs in not meeting infrastructure challenge. The report argued that public debt and
PPPs have advantage of spreading infrastructure costs over time. Australia's level of public debt is
low (6% of GDP compared with limits set at 30% in UK and 60% in US). Some claim that
increases would put credit rating / interest rates at risk - which is invalid. However the argument for
greater use of public debt is not an argument against using PPPs. Infrastructure projects can be risky,
and there can be gains where these risks are shared with private partners. The key to successful
PPPs is that returns accurately reflect risks. All infrastructure funding options should be considered
(Fahrer J., 'PPPs have valuable place in funding mix', FR, 8/12/03)
Though the PPPs have been little used and remain controversial, public debate about problems
(eg at Sydney's Cross City Tunnel) has helped improve methods [1]
However there are cases in developing countries which suggest that huge costs can be
imposed on governments where the latter are forced to take
responsibility for outcomes in infrastructure service markets
involving private providers.
In 1987 the Philippines power sector was haphazardly liberalized -
which resulted in acute electricity shortages in the early 1990s. Then
government started to provide incentives for electricity development (eg
tax holidays, duty exemptions, take-or-pay provisions; loan guarantees).
Now it is committed to paying for power for which there is no demand. As
supply increased, power became more expensive (contrary to normal
economic principles). Collusion between officials and foreign power
companies compounded the problem (Smith P 'High price paid for power
deals', FR, 13/8/02)
By November 2004 an industry view was emerging that the use of PPP's might
have stalled in Australia [1]
. For example:
- It seems clear that Queensland [1,
2,
3]
and Victoria are backing away from the use of this mechanism, though it
continues to be heavily used in NSW [1];
- in NSW government indicated that private operation of public hospitals
would not be allowed because of disastrous experience with a PPP [1]
The Commonwealth Government (who is being asked to
make taxation and legislative changes to facilitate PPPs) had also shown some
hesitancy.
Federal government has few opportunities to use PPPs and doesn't plan to
encourage states to do so. Insurance and accounting worries undermined the PPP
process for $400m naval patrol boats. Controversy over UK government's plan to
let private sector build and run schools and hospitals also causes government
concern. Federal Government is being encouraged by industry to clear the way
(with legislation and tax changes) for state PPPs (Taylor L. 'Minchen won't
commit to PPPs', FR, 11/7/02)
Hopes for a new era of nation-building projects through
PPPs have been thrown into doubt by fiasco over funding of navy patrol boat. A
three year tending process (in which companies invested millions of dollars)
has been turned on its head because federal government did not check how
financing of the project would be viewed by the Auditor General. Cabinet
decided to scrap the process after the AG decided that many of the costs should
be entered in the federal budget in its first year (Wilson P. 'Government
stuff-up sinks patrol boat bid', A, 11/7/02)
However in 2005 a more supportive approach to PPPs was announced [1,
2]. And the NSW government [1];
the Brisbane City Council [1]
and the Queensland Government [1]
all indicated a determination to make use of this model.
However in 2006 attention was being drawn to very severe
problems in Victoria's infrastructure system in which the
PPP models Queensland copied had been developed. For example:
- rising costs and lengthening delays
are suspected to be due to trying to manage
record infrastructure programs in the face of loss of specialist skills and
intense competition for skills [1];
and
- very large expenditures over 7 years Victoria has
achieved little in terms of improving infrastructure / services because of bad
management [1].
Intrinsic Problems
Unfortunately there are likely to be intrinsic
complexities with PPPs (ones that will not go away because they relate to the
character of typical public goods and services) not just 'teething' problems.
Firstly, Public goods and services tend to be qualitatively
different from typical private goods and services.
The goods and services whose production and distribution is
traditionally managed through a market involving private providers tend
to be individual 'things' which can be treated separately and defined
quite clearly.
Public goods and services, by contrast tend to be those which are:
- natural monopolies (eg involve large uneconomic-to-duplicate
investments; provide no practical way to collect revenue; or are
enjoyed whether or not a particular person chooses to pay);
- subject to large positive or negative 'externalities', ie spill-over
effects on other functions; or
- affected by political value judgments about equity or the general
community interest relative to private interests.
These characteristics of public goods and services cause them to be
intrinsically complex. This has several consequences:
- the basic character of what governments deal with is quite
different to that of private firms. The latter's focus is rightly on
producing 'things' (outputs / projects), while governments' main focus
must be on managing the relationships amongst such 'things'.
- managing this complexity is costly no matter whether they are
produced by public sector agencies or through private firms (where the
cost of complexity might be reflected in the 'packaging fees' associated with PPPs). If the complexity is ignored in order to reduce costs, then
eventually the function will be seen to be failing.
- in particular many types of infrastructure involve networks where the elements
are highly interconnected - and there is a need to plan / manage the
system as a whole. The focus which PPPs encourage on individual
projects, and the introduction of private interest considerations, can
make it essentially impossible to deal with the system as a whole.
Example: Melbourne's City Link freeway system, which was
developed under a PPP arrangement reportedly had to involve a
provision for government to compensate the developer for any other
changes in the transport system that might reduce their revenues.
Creating a few such links in a region's transport system would
ensure that future development of the network became essentially
impossible.
Moreover:
- one observer suggested that the provision of infrastructure
Australia wide is in disarray because of these problems [1]
- the development of privately funded toll roads on a user pays
basis in parallel with 'free' public facilities creates for transport
infrastructure complexities in management, pricing and controlling demand
exactly like that which affects health and education services [1]
- privatization of Melbourne's public transport is seen to have
resulted in 'splintering' of urban systems which has created
complexity and dysfunctions;
- surface traffic has been
deliberately distorted to force traffic into Sydney tunnels to make them
profitable [1,
2,
3];
- for such goods and services, it can be very hard or impossible to
define clearly what is required, because some are subject to complex inter-linkages with other functions, or
are subject to political value judgments (noting that the political
system exists partly as a means for managing the fact that our complex
human reality can be interpreted in many different ways). As such goods
and services are hard to specify exactly in advance (which is one
reason that the classic rule-bound bureaucracy is seen to be rigid), it
is correspondingly difficult for contractors to meet the unclear needs
that are actually presented in practice;
Consider: Only 20% of public servants involved in
outsourcing consider this a success (in Australia, Canada, NZ,
Singapore, South Africa, Spain, UK and US). Savings of 20% were said
to be achieved, but hard to measure. Baseline (pre-contracting)
costs are often not available and changes in the volume and type of
work required under the contract typically eliminated the relevance
of such benchmarks after 6 months. Contract management was estimated
as about 8-10% of the contract price (Jay C 'Public service no fan
of outsourcing', Financial Review, 15/2/02);
- natural monopolies tend to be large complex undertakings - and this
is the reason that PPPs are being sought for integrated design,
construction and operation. However because of their complexity it is
very costly to duplicate technical knowledge of the undertaking. Thus,
in a PPP process, the exclusiveness of the contractor's detailed
technical knowledge presents the public sector with great difficulty in
defining what is required without simply relying on the contractor
(which leads to risks outlined below).
- for such goods and services it tends to be impossible for
governments to allow projects to fail - either because they constitute an
essential service or because they are an integral part of a large system
whose integrity depends on them. Thus there can seldom be a genuine
transfer of risk to the private sector.
Instances have been identified in Victoria where full privatization
of some infrastructure has resulted in situation where the process could
fail because those services could not be successfully disentangled from
public interest considerations [1].
Second, the knowledge and skills in government agencies that is
required for contract management may simply not be available when most
delivery of goods and services is carried out externally. For example,
massive problems appear to be emerging in managing PPPs in Victoria in
2004 [1],
and that state's overall infrastructure system appeared subsequently to be
in very severe difficulties.
Also: see 'Troubled
waters' (Peterson D. Courier Mail, 2/6/01) which deals with
competency questions in relation to major cost-blow-outs in Queensland.
In the 1990s government agencies were 'de-engineered' (eg
through outsourcing) in the hope of gaining lower costs, better
quality and more flexibility. A leader in this process was Department
of Main Roads Western Australia, which has recently studied the
results. Overall about 30% of technical staff were lost, with up to
65% in some areas. The Department was then perceived as an uninformed
purchaser of services. The process also destroyed the possibility of
career opportunities for staff. In some areas all experience resides
with one or two individuals, with no succession options. Furthermore
technical staff moved into project management - with a resulting loss
of technical competence. Traditionally the Department had been the key
organization involved in training road engineering practitioners for
WA. The Department's engineering capabilities were now believed to be
below the critical mass required to be sustainable. (Yates A.
'Bringing engineers back into public service', Civil Engineering
Australia, May 2002)
In the UK, government appears to have been frequently
'out-negotiated' by private firms (Marris S. 'Nice
public work if you can get it', Australian, 17/6/02)
The loss of professional competencies will be magnified when a
Public Service is subjected to manipulation to ensure its uncritical
compliance with political directives - as has become normal in the
1990s (see
The
Growing Case for a Professional Public Service).
A similar, though less fundamental, constraint is that where government
agencies lack 'hand's on' involvement it is likely to be harder to
identify situations where valid political judgments about equity or the
community interest would support CSO payments .
From reports about US experience, where heavy reliance has sometimes been
placed on private contracting for public goods and services delivery, it
appeared to be concluded (in sources that the author can no longer locate) that
all that is achieved is to exchange the problem of trying to achieve efficiency
in service delivery in a political environment (ie in a government agency) for
the even more difficult problem of effective contract management in what can
sometimes be a snouts-in-the-trough political environment.
The result is that it is difficult (a) to turn efficiency gains through
private delivery into real costs savings after taking account of problems in
contract management and (b) to satisfy public expectations in relation to the
quality of services delivered.
None of this implies that PPPs are not appropriate ways of dealing with
some infrastructure needs - merely that they are unlikely to be beneficial
if applied widely.
Distorting / Corrupting Government?
A difficulty likely to arise from PV in the longer term is the
distortion of political and public administration processes.
Priority will tend to be given to infrastructure which is relatively easy to
fund - eg that for which user-pays arrangements can be established. It has been
suggested that toll-roads have gained priority at the expense of many other
types of essential infrastructure [1]
Also where
firms are the only ones involved in providing public services, they tend to
have the best (or only) information about what is required, and this allows
self-interested lobbying and collusion with 'captured' or job-seeking officials
to dominate (as in the US 'military industrial complex', and Japan's
'construction state'). How, for example, can anyone outside this 'system'
know what is needed or what is a fair price to pay?
In Australia concerns about the need for transparency and accountability to
guard against 'funny deals' are already being expressed (Gray J.
'Transparency-accountability keys to success', Financial review,
11/2/02)
Also: The NSW government says there was no
political interference in the tender process for a $100m new transport
ticketing system - but, as government can terminate employment contracts
without good reason, ministers can readily exert covert pressure on public
servants. The law doesn't allow ministers to instruct their deputies
regarding decisions or recommendations - but no one complains when they
do. No one can now protect senior public servants. Department heads are
compromised by their own tenuous employment terms, and Public Service
Commissioners are impotent. The Humphrey inquiry into federal IT
outsourcing showed that public servants - if given anonymity - provided
advice about flaws in the system that wasn't given to an open
parliamentary inquiry. The 2000 Clayton inquiry in South Australia showed
that some public servants would lie under oath rather than say anything to
embarrass ministers. Anti-corruption bodies (in NSW, Queensland and
WA) are supposed to deal with such matters - but waste their time on minor
matters. They are nervous about investigating the upper echelons of
government. Parliament needs to prod anti-corruption bodies to look at the
big end of government and leave small issues to police. (Harris T.
'Bureaucrats self-protection', Financial Review, 15/1/02)
Brisbane's former Lord Mayor has been appointed chairman of the troubled airport
railway operator - Airtrain City Link. This risks criticism over conflict
of interest because the council is considering corporate involvement in
big infrastructure projects - such as a $1bn tollway tunnel under the
city. Cr Soorley forged close links with ABN AMRO (Airtrain bond holders)
through his advocacy of public private partnerships. And one of
Airtrain's key backers (Transfield) made a $30,000 donation to the Labor
party in 2001. (Owen R. 'Soorley to head Airtrain board', Courier
Mail, 21/3/02) Disputes have emerged with state government over efforts by Brisbane's Lord Mayor to arrange a
post-retirement job with Airtrain (Franklin M 'Labor pains', CM, 2/11/02)
NSW premier (whose government made a feature of
involving private investors, especially Macquarie Bank, in public
infrastructure) resigned unexpectedly, and then took well paid job acting for Macquarie Bank.
[1,
2].
There has been concerns about the emergence of a 'tunnel-industry complex'
comparable with US military-industrial complex. [1]
Conflict of interest concerns are arising when senior public servants leap
directly into private enterprise [1]
In Australia PPPs are seen to have allowed expensive and highly geared
private finance for low-cost public borrowing - while what is going on is
concealed behind a veil of 'commercial in confidence' provisions [1]
More private profit than public good has been seen to follow from PPPs whose
details remain murky. PPPs have proven popular with incompetent state
governments [1]
In 2014 there was said to be public concern with: the easy money that
political insiders could from participation in ventures which gained a
government contract; the extravagant salaries allowances that were being paid to
those involved; murky business-political links associated with large 'success'
fees; and the payment of large and secretive political donations to gain
government support [1]
The fact that some privately funded infrastructure could
only be profitable with a government subsidy clearly is a further
complication.
Queensland's systems for planning approvals to urban development proposals
appears to be at risk of being 'corrupted' by PPPs. The North Bank proposal placed government into the invidious position of being the advocate for a
project that would be privately funded and thus inclined to override the role
of local authorities in evaluating and controlling such investments (see 'Beattie threatens North
Bank takeover').
Accountability difficulties have also been encountered in Queensland related
to whether decisions be made to provide exclusive mandates to particular companies to
protect their intellectual property or whether a public tender should be required in all cases
to ensure accountability [1]?
Conflict of interest problems and a lack of competitive neutrality can be
expected because QIC (the state government's investment arm on whose
performance the state budget bottom line depends) has launched a $1bn
infrastructure investment fund. [1]
Government can potentially determine how much infrastructure users would have
to pay - which would in turn determine the financial benefits to its own
financial subsidiary which is supposed to be operating in a competitive
environment.
The escalation of lobbying about the need for massive additional spending and
for private financing, by organizations representing private infrastructure
interests that was apparent by early 2005 clearly illustrates the way in which
public perception and government decisions can be distorted (especially in the
absence of a competent independent Public Service). This has also become a
matter of public concern:
Australia's ports, railways and water systems have been starved of funds because state
governments have been lured into dubious private sector tollway deals that require hundreds of
millions of dollars in government subsidies. [1].
PPPs are seen to get higher priority
than better projects because of pressure from private firms [1].
Governments should avoid PPPs led by investment banks, as these would tend to be driven by
financial engineering, rather than by concern for the best interests of the community
[1].
The potential for private interests to dominate in public policy (at the
expense of others) was also illustrated by complaints made about conflict of
interest affecting an individual appointed to the Prime Minister's taskforce on
removing obstacles to infrastructure development [1]
And in the UK in the mid 19th century it was the conflicts of public and
private interests in public services that first led to the creation of a
professional Civil Service as a result of the Northcote-Trevellan Report.
|
Queensland's special problems
|
B. Queensland's Infrastructure System is more Complex and
Needs Fundamental Renewal
Victoria's situation with respect to infrastructure seems to be a lot simpler
than that in Queensland, so that the Partnerships Victoria / UK models
are even less appropriate in Queensland.
The Economic Productivity Question
In Victoria most infrastructure services that could contribute to raising
economic productivity were privatized, whereas in Queensland they remain part
of the public sector under corporatisation and commercialization arrangements.
Thus, in Queensland, much greater emphasis has to be given to competitive
enterprising processes in planning infrastructure, if:
- economic productivity is to be promoted - which would strengthen the tax
base and provide the most realistic way of overcoming the growing
problem of infrastructure financing (see Section C below);
and
- the financial viability of government's commercialized and corporatised
infrastructure service providers (on which the over-stretched state budget is
now critically dependent) are to be ensured. This applies particularly where
infrastructure service providers face external competition.
In Victoria this can be neglected, and what remains as public infrastructure
can be treated (as PV does) in a very conventional (government
determined) way, without significant economic or budgetary cost.
An aside: In a Comment
on the 2001 Infrastructure Report Card (produced by the Institution of
Engineers Australia and others), it was suggested that the analysts had
overlooked the fact that governments could often not now commit to
infrastructure on a policy basis (and that the Report Card, with its
recommendations mainly to government, was thus addressed to the wrong
audience).
In Victoria's case this constraint is obvious where government is no
longer the provider of key infrastructure. In Queensland, on the other hand,
government can not commit in cases where market-oriented competitive
processes (rather than consultative / political processes) must be allowed
in planning economic infrastructure if productivity and the earnings of
government enterprises are to be raised and community-service-obligation
costs are to be minimized.
Queensland's Infrastructure Planning Problem
It is also clear that Queensland is not coping with the need to create an
effective system for planning infrastructure (see
Problems in Infrastructure Planning and Delivery), and that the process for
strategic planning of the core functions of government suffers similar weaknesses (see
Evaluation of 'Managing for Outcomes').
It is also noteworthy that the definition of infrastructure adopted in
2000 by Queensland's Department of State Development's
Strategic Infrastructure
for Queensland's Growth is much broader than that under PV
(which was limited to physical assets and IT services) .
Queensland's definition appears to include a lot of 'soft
infrastructure' (eg economic organizations). The problem is that, while
the latter are important, they can not be effectively provided by
government (and certainly not through anything like the process used for
'hard' infrastructure) - see
Comments on 'Strategic Infrastructure for Queensland's Growth'
On the other hand Queensland's PPP arrangements do not seem to apply to
many non-infrastructure public services, which are covered under PV.
Furthermore Queensland's (draft) Public Private
Partnership Guidance Material (DSD, April 2002) and the Commonwealth's
AusLink scheme for transport infrastructure simply add further layers of
administrative complexity to this already-ineffectual machinery.
Outline of Queensland Guidance Material: Queensland released a PPP
policy in September 2001. A partnership approach is intended to apply
public and private contributions to best achieve value for money
infrastructure services. A critical issue in infrastructure delivery is
the risks that Government confronts - and some of these can best be
managed by the private sector. The PPP approach thus allows costs to be
contained while government maintains effective control over infrastructure
to meet community needs. Many different mechanism can be involved (eg DBO,
DBFO, BOOT). Government must carefully investigate technical and financial
issues, as a PPP may not always be the best option. Principles
underpinning the Guidance Material involve: value for money services, and
risk sharing; encouraging private innovation; optimizing asset
utilization; and integrated whole-of-life infrastructure management.
Felicity will be a key requirement, as is: encompassing both 'hard' and
'soft' infrastructure; consistency with State Purchasing Policy
guidelines; dealing with specific issues such as risk management, project
resourcing and probity / process governance. Other principles include;
clarity; competitive processes; consistency with other government
requirements; analytical rigor; protection of genuine intellectual
property; transparency / accountability; and clear information about
project outcomes. The process involves six stages (a) service
identification - by departments through their strategic planning processes
with projects over $30m being considered for PPP with help of a Taskforce
and DSD. Unsolicited proposals will be assessed against existing planning
frameworks (b) preliminary assessment of delivery options allowing a CBRC
decision (c) preparation of a business case through a Government
project team - including: both a Public Sector Comparator model and a
Partnership model; an assessment of all risks, and service performance
requirements that will form the basis of contractual conditions; and a
cabinet decision (d) calling expressions of interest - which result in a
technically and financially qualified short-list (e) seeking binding bids,
and proceeding to a formal contract (f) contract management through a
specialist team within departments. Unsolicited proposals will be
assessed against agency plans, and processed either under the Guidelines
or as an exclusive mandate. Special attention is given to risk
management and probity within the process. A Government Project team (for
technical issues), a Project Steering Committee (to deal with commercial
and policy issues) and a Project Director will also be required for a
project. A Probity Auditor will be engaged to ensure that processes
are followed fairly. Progress
The Guidance Material represents progress in that:
- it does outline a possible PPP process - largely derived from
Victoria's experiences;
- it finally specifies who (ie various function agencies through
their strategic planning processes) is expected to plan infrastructure.
But this leaves significant difficulties.
- The PPP procedure was apparently copied from Victoria, whose
situation (and that of the UK from which PV itself was
derived) is simpler than Queensland's in that most Victorian
economic infrastructure that is capable of contributing to economic
productivity was privatized and thus freed to respond to market
demands - and does not thus have to be dealt with by the state
infrastructure planning system;
- The fact that government agencies are to specify infrastructure
requirements in areas subject to direct or indirect competition and
to user-pays will place service providers (whether public or
private) in a difficult financial predicament - being required to
provide facilities that may have political priority but
less-than-possible market demand. Thus:
- while the PPP arrangement may enable private firms to carry
risks related to construction, such firms may often find it
necessary to insist that government carry all ongoing commercial
risks that arise from the original decision about what
infrastructure services to provide;
- the expectation that GOC's will provide dividends and tax
equivalent payments to support the state budget is unlikely to be
met;
- There is, as noted above, no credible government machinery for
planning infrastructure from which projects are to feed into the PPP
process. In particular, weakness introduced into agency
infrastructure planning in the 1990s were the likely reason that the
Department of State Development produced a
State Infrastructure Plan in 2001. The latter (defective)
Plan has now been ignored in the PPP Guidance Material, leaving
agency strategic planning as the way in which projects are to
originate. However, as noted above,
Managing for Outcomes
(supposedly an integrated process for accrual accounting, output
budgeting and strategic planning by agencies) is also unrealistic.
- the PPP process seems to be complex (and thus will become an
'industry' in itself);
- the Guidance Material treats PPP issues as the main
consideration, which will make it very difficult to get all
technical aspects of projects right. For example:
- the Guidance Material apparently envisages projects under the
control of two parallel project teams with different goals -
an arrangement whose ability to integrate the complex technical
requirements with the equally complex legal and commercial
requirements remains to be demonstrated; furthermore
- unless decisions about capital issues are made by those with
detailed concern also for ongoing operations, it is possible to
achieve the appearance of capital savings whilst worsening the
public finance position overall. For example, annual operating
costs for hospitals can be 50% of capital costs, and one informed
observer [whose assertions the author has not personally
confirmed] has suggested that Queensland has suffered
considerable long term financial damage (and may be unable to use
some hospital facilities that have been constructed) due to a
failure to integrate these questions in a $2.3 bn hospital
expansion program.
- probity concerns are (rightly) seen as a critical
consideration - yet the emphasis that must be given to this will
ensure that (honest) Public Service staff will be more concerned
with protecting themselves than with whether the project is
'right';
- if technical specifications are defective, contractors have an
easy path to claiming extras;
- choosing between a Public Sector Comparator and a Partnership
model will involve heroic (ie arbitrary) assumptions, and involves
transforming what (to be fair) really needs to be a dynamic
competition between different parties into a committee's
deliberation;
- the specialized and separated PPP processing within agencies of
investments that involve very large public expenditures will make
real accountability difficult, and invite corrupt collusion. A
Probity Auditor concerned with whether 'correct processes' are
followed, but unaware of detailed technical requirements, will be
unable to guard against such abuses.
One observer suggested in 2004 that Queensland agencies seek
wherever possible to keep projects away from the PPP process, because
those projects otherwise are lost into a 'black hole' for 18 months.
AusLink - Curing or Compounding the Problem? The Commonwealth
Transport Minister has proposed arrangements for transport
infrastructure (traditionally the infrastructure area most heavily
funded by the Commonwealth) that seek to 'revolutionize infrastructure
development allowing the private sector to drive planning and
development rather than bureaucrats'
States are concerned that methods to better coordinate
development of roads and railways should not result in reduced
federal funding. With private firms now heavily involved in
owning infrastructure, AusLink will include those firms in the
planning, building and ongoing running of roads, railways and
ports. The 20 year plan will involve greater use of PPPs. It will
end the dominance of roads in thinking about transport - perhaps
with more funding for transport hubs involving rail. Shadow tolls
would also be considered. ACID suggested that: shadow tolls would
require tax changes; that rail networks faced 35 regulatory
organizations and 11 different signaling systems. The Victorian
Government suggested that the transport system needs overhaul -
but not via AusLink. There was concern that federal funds
previously given to the states for roads, would now also go for
other projects which had been state funded. (Marris S. 'States
fear federal road funding cuts', Australian,
23/5/02).
AusLink envisages a national indicative planning process for all
forms of transport infrastructure - with any entity able to seek
funding to participate in implementation.
AusLink's (private-sector driven) PPP planning and development
arrangement is inconsistent with the government driven PPP process
that the states have created. Given the problems in the Queensland
Guidance Material mentioned above, this may not be a bad thing.
However:
- AusLink does mean that there could be no uniform national
PPP system;
- while a constructive indicative planning process might be
feasible, there are potential traps such as (a) trying to produce
such a plan analytically - because central planners can never gain
enough information to do so or (b) relying on project proposals from
self interested infrastructure providers seeking competitive
advantages - because of the potential for the whole process to
become a political dog-fight or to foster corruption;
- the
major transport problem which Queensland faces is in SE
Queensland - where the key to progress is probably not just more
infrastructure investment but rather a fundamental decision about
what the philosophy / architecture of the transport system as a
whole is to be - so that coherence between the various elements in
the system can be gained. This requirement is similar to the need
for an agreed architecture which is common to all components on the
Internet if they are to interact. The AusLink process would
appear to make it hard for anyone other than the Commonwealth
Government to decide such an architecture - and also ensure that
they did not do so either.
What is not at all clear is that central control of transport
strategy is likely to lead to satisfactory outcomes noting that:
- a highly centralized transport planning process would separate
transport from other closely related regional issues such as land
use;
- the most conspicuous example of total centralization of a
previously state function now seems to be in crisis - noting what
many observers suggest about universities; and
- federal regulation of telecommunications does not seem to be a
major success.
|
Increasing Funding |
C. Overcoming the Real Problem - The Need to Boost the Tax
Base
PPPs are being proposed because a funding problem is perceived in providing
infrastructure (and other public services). However the funding problem arises
primarily from weaknesses in the tax base due to defective economic management
strategy, and PPPs are not the best (or even a credible) solution.
That there is an underlying public funding problem is undoubted.
Considering Queensland for example:
About
Queensland's Budget illustrates (amongst many other points):
- the general pressure on public finance (prior to the emergence of a
presumably-transitory economic / property boom), and the difficulty of
recording a surplus;
- the apparent state government intention to reduce public
capital formation at one time, despite general expectations
that infrastructure investments should increase.
Also: an inquiry that the Queensland Local Government Association
is undertaking into mechanisms to Fund Queensland's Road and Transport
Infrastructure clearly identifies various studies of funding needs for this
sector which suggest a probable funding gap (see
LGA website)
However, while PPPs will presumably be relevant to some
infrastructure situations, they are not the best way to try to overcome the
funding problem generally, because:
- if government is the ultimate purchaser of of the infrastructure on
behalf of the community then mobilizing private funds in constructing
that infrastructure can not actually result in any increase in the amount of
infrastructure that can be provided (Quiggin)
unless:
- cost savings are achieved through greater efficiency (eg through life-cycle
design). Unfortunately such expected gains may be lost in the contractual difficulties created by: the intrinsic
character of 'public' goods and services; reduced public sector technical
skills; and by potential corrupting of administration (see
Section A above);
- direct user-charges are applied (eg toll roads) - though it is noted that user charges could be applied without PPPs;
- a major reason, discussed further below, for the funding shortfall is
that defective past economic management tactics have resulted in a weak tax
base - though this is not the only cause of the weakness of the tax base;
- the main 'advantage' of PPPs in terms of financing may be that they might deceptively give the impression that governments' debt position is
strong - because government does not acquire a debt which has to be serviced
(see 'Setting off on the PPP road'). Rather it may incur
a roughly-equal ongoing contractual obligation in relation to capital costs
(plus a contractual obligation for operational costs).
Accounting complexities: In July 2002 the Commonwealth Auditor General correctly pointed out that (under an accrual accounting system)
accrued
future expenses through PPPs should be brought into the annual budget in the year
in which an obligation is incurred.
There had previously been concern that the proposed shift to Public Private Partnerships for
infrastructure could
obscure public
liabilities. This was because, rather than incurring an explicit
debt which needs to be serviced, using PPPs on anything but a
user-pays project government enters a long term contract
for the purchase of goods and services. The latter will usually involve an
even greater commitment that includes both capital and operational
costs, but this would not be included as a liability
under traditional capital accounting arrangements [see also Quiggin J. 'Enron's
Australian cousin' Financial Review, 28/2/02. In
Enron's case, the company gained notoriety by creating phoney
'partnerships' in which its liabilities were concealed]. Unless a way can be found to capitalize future operating cost
commitments, this decision may make it harder for governments to use PPPs widely
(especially for services such as health and education that would
involve large operating costs for which government was the purchaser). For example, if Queensland enters into PPP arrangements for projects with a capital cost of (say) $1bn in which
government is the ultimate customer, this would now no longer provide an
effective way to 'conceal' the $1bn debt. Rather the capital and
multi-year operating costs of the PPPs could have to be
included in
the budget (perhaps by including the $1bn in the capital account
and all government commitments to future operating costs in the
operating account). The net effect could be to increase the state's
operating deficit by
something like $2-3bn (and to create a non-capital asset - ie the
present value of certain future services which would need to be heavily
discounted for both time and risk). Only user-pays projects would seem not
to require this sort of accounting treatment.
In the post-Enron environment the 'advantages' of the latter form of creative
accounting are likely to be transient. And the Commonwealth Auditor General
has reportedly determined that most costs in a PPP
contract should be treated as an accrued expense in the first year.
None-the-less accounting reforms do not yet cover the situation where ongoing
costs are funded on a user-pays basis, and the effect is to shift debts
off-balance-sheet into a partnership by privatizing a form of public revenue
raising.
That Queensland has a weak tax base by Australian standards is
indicated by the Inquiry into Commonwealth Grants Commission Arrangements that
'donor' states (NSW, Victoria and WA) have launched.
Why? The 'donor' states are concerned that the Grants Commission
recommends redistribution of Commonwealth tax revenues to Queensland that
it derives from their citizens and businesses - and they can not
understand why this should be so if Queensland now has a well-developed
economy (see Comments on Inquiry into
Commonwealth Grants Commission Arrangements) The need for the
Grants Commission to recommend such Commonwealth generosity to Queensland
arises from the fact that Queensland's tax base (approximated by gross
state product / capita) is something like 15% below the national average.
This per-capita income gap is due particularly to defective economic
strategies that Queensland used in the 1980s and previously (ie the
pursuit of low value-added industries such as tourism, and basic
commodities exports) (see the above-mentioned
Comments).
However Queensland's relatively weak tax base does not account for the fact
that many other administrations are now also facing funding challenges that
force them (for example) to look more deeply into Commonwealth Grants
Commission practices. The general funding problem has two apparent
causes:
- the constraint in a globalised economy on the tax rates that can be
applied without seriously risking emigration of industry and skilled
individuals; and
- defective economic management tactics that were applied (ie by the UK and
Australia) in the face of a challenge requiring economic diversification in
the 1980s. Emphasis was given to:
- market liberalisation to encourage firms (and others) become more
competitive;
- reducing the cost of government (to increase incentives and reduce
some input costs). The latter was achieved by cutting government spending,
and by applying 'business-like' methods (sometimes through privatisation)
in the expectation that these would lead to cost savings
The problem with the latter response was that:
- it did not adequately boost economic productivity - see
Impact of Economic Liberalization in
Australia. Australia's 'growth' and 'productivity' performance in the
1990s is widely described as exceptional and 'miraculous'. However, while
performance was improved on previous decades, the perception of a 'miracle'
depended heavily on constant devaluations to price Australians into jobs, and
to lower the real reference point against which some 'growth' (ie in
activities feeding into exports) would be measured;
- better options existed - eg see
Defects in Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes. Those options
involved creating democratically-endorsed but not-politically-run
institutional arrangements to accelerate 'learning' within industrial
clusters, and so gain competitiveness and productivity advantages similar to
those that innovation can provide to individual firms;
- public spending was sometimes merely deferred, rather than permanently
avoided - with the result now a perceived spending backlog.
In part these problems arose because the attempt to reform government on a
'business-like' basis substantially eroded its ability to be 'government-like'
- as is well illustrated by the problems in competently managing strategic
economic change that were generated in Queensland by the mismanagement of
public sector 'reform' (see
Towards Good Government in Queensland).
Trying to raise economic performance through lifting the efficiency of the
public sector, rather than through developing the economy, appears to be a
fundamental mistake that countries like the UK and Australia have been making
for more than a decade.
If emphasis was given to developing the productivity of the economy by
methods like those suggested in
Defects
in Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes, then:
- significant improvements in the tax base could be achieved (see indicative
calculation below); and
- tax rates would be able to be increased (at least marginally) while still
attracting industry and skilled individuals (because clusters of integrated
productivity-supporting functions would exist).
Indicative calculation
The extent to which the tax base for public goods and services in
Australia has been sacrificed through defective economic management in
the 1990s can be indicated VERY roughly as follows (an estimate that
could undoubtedly be significantly improved).
Assume that during the 1990s Australia's population grew 1.5% pa and
the economy grew 3.5%pa in $A. If so, then per capita $A production grew
at around 2% pa. If productivity growth was equally attributable to
increases in capital and to the growth of knowledge (a fair assumption),
then something like a 1% pa growth could be attributed to 'learning'
within organizations (eg to innovation).
If methods such as those suggested were deployed to accelerate
'learning' within economic systems as well then it is likely that this
component of productivity growth could be doubled (ie yielding an extra
1% pa growth). It is reasonable to expect this because (a) Australia
still has scope for considerable economic catch-up (b) other economies
that have achieved economic miracles (by the use of similar methods) have
been able to double their rate of growth.
Over 10 years this would increase GDP (a fair approximation
of the tax base) by something like 11% and create strong / integrated
industrial clusters in which a 10% increase in taxation rate might be
achieved whilst still being very attractive to industry.
Thus an overall increase in tax revenues of over 20% might now be
available - and it appears that this is the order of magnitude of
increase in public spending that could overcome the funding gaps that are
currently seen to affect infrastructure and other public services.
While many Australian jurisdictions are now copying the UK's PPP approach to
coping with a lack of public revenue, protocols for more useful
private-public partnership models have apparently been explored in the USA (ie
to enhance the productivity of industry clusters) and it might be timely now to
take such alternatives more seriously.
However a more general review of options for public financing could also be
needed, if the underlying public funding pressures that Queensland is facing requires more
than the increase in revenue that can be achieved by accelerating economic
development (ie through creating a stronger tax base, and an ability to remain
attractive as an industrial location despite higher tax rates)
|