|
|
CPDS Home Contact | Competing Thought Cultures |
Introduction This document was initiated as a result of a report by an observer in Tokyo (Leon Wolff) that the newly-elected Democratic Party of Japan wanted to 're-Japanise' Japan (ie get its 'identity' back). An exchange of emails about what this might imply is included below, which started from the suggestion that: (a) it is unclear what 'identity' Japan wants back: and (b) the world faces severe economic challenges partly because of features of Japanese economic methods that were the basis of economic 'miracles' in East Asia - but depend on financial imbalances that are now recognised to be significant in causing the global financial crisis.. Some clarification of what reclaiming Japan's identity might mean subsequently emerged.
|
|
An
Exchange of Views
|
Email sent 19/9/09
Leon Wolff, Re: 'Japan wants its identity back', couriermail.com.au, 18/9/09 I noted that your article argued that Australia might benefit from Japan's rejection of 'Americanisation'. However, I should like to suggest for your consideration that: (a) Japan has been trying to reject 'Americanisation' since 1854, so it is not at all clear what 'identity' Japan wants back; and (b) the world faces a serious economic challenge partly because (as your article noted) Japan's most recent 'Americanisation' was only superficial.
While its new Prime Minister may wish to make Japan more Japanese, it needs to be recognised that Japan's 'Japanese-ness' (and the economic models that others in East Asia adapted from Japan's methods, in order to emulate Japan's rapid economic growth and development) have arguably::
In brief East Asian economic models (including Japan's) have involved the allocation of resources by consensus amongst nationalistic elites and their social subordinates rather than by a capitalistic search for profit - and the result has been inefficient use of capital and a consequent need for export-dominated economic strategies in order to generate large cash flows from current account surpluses so as to protect financial institutions with suspect balance sheets (see Understanding East Asia's Economic Models, and Why Japan cannot deregulate its financial system). The result has been the international financial imbalances, which played a significant role in the emergence of the GFC (see Impacting the Global Economy). While I haven't seen Yukio Hatoyama's political philosophy, that expressed by Mr Rudd in his The Monthly essay (which you suggested was similar) seemed superficial as an explanation of the GFC (see A Social Democratic Alternative to 'Neo-Liberalism'?). Moreover initial discussions by the G20 also adopted an unrealistically narrow perspective on the causes of the GFC (see G20: Peace for our Time'?) - though both the US and Europe have reportedly now started insisting that the imbalances question receives attention (see China scorns focus on imbalances). Furthermore there are strong indications that East Asia's economic models (including Japan's) would no longer be viable in an environment in which large international financial imbalances are prevented (see Unsustainable Economic Models?). If so, then Japan (and eventually China and many others) will have no choice but to seek a different 'identity'. Japan has arguably 'wanted its identity back' since Commodore Perry's 'Black Ships' forcefully opened Tokugawa Japan to world trade in 1854. One must wonder which identify Japan now wants back as the false 'American' mask of the post-1990 era is removed. Yukio Hatoyama seems to rule out Japan's post-Pacific War merchant identity, which involved bureaucratic orchestration of the development of consumer-oriented industries behind the LDP's mask of liberal democracy, Might the 'community-spirited' identity that Yukio Hatoyama now advocates be that of the pre-1854 isolationist feudal shogunate, or that of the pre-Pacific War militaristic imperium? If the latter, Japan's neighbours have cause for some nervousness. Australia will be unlikely to benefit if Japan's future identity is reclaimed from Japan's past, My guess is that (in the spirit of Shinto) the identity that Japan will find that it has little choice about wanting 'back' is likely to be something entirely new - perhaps becoming more truly Americanised, though the DPJ obviously could not say this to the Japanese people. John Craig |
Response 19/9/09 |
Email received from Leon Wolff (19/9/09) Thank you for your comments on my recent op-ed piece in The Courier Mail. I am deighted that someone actually read it let alone critically evaluated my core arguments. It will be very interesting to see how Prime Minister Hatoyama implements his new strategy to distance himself from the trappings of 'Americanisation'. His stance on 'Americanisation' may simply have been a 'straw man' argument to endear himself to an electorate frustrated with Japan's ongoing economic woes and rising employment instability. Given the whipping his party gave to the Liberal Democratic Party in the last election, this was clearly a successful ploy. Your response seems to suggest that a 'Japanese' way forward could ultimately be disastrous for a return to global economic health. This is based on the view that Japan is a development state -- rather than a true capitalist economy -- in which a cadre of elite bureaucrats micro-managed the economy. This is a commonly argued position, but its empirical bases are suspect. First, there are no laws authorising bureaucrats to 'direct' companies as to what to do. Second, to the extent that they can manage the economy, bureaucrats have, at best, advisory powers (called 'administrative guidance') which they can use to influence economic decisions. However, companies are free to reject this advice, often do and, if threatened with adverse consequences, successfully sue for damages. Third, there are fewer bureaucrats in Japan per head of population than in most leading capitalist economies in the world, especially the US and including Australia. Those who advocate elite control over the economy have failed to explain how such a small group of people can exercise control over such a large economic order. Finally, even if bureaucrats did have the power, energy and will to control the economy, their concerns would have been directed at larger industries. Yet it is the SME sector -- not large conglomerates such as Sony and Mitsubishi -- that are the primary source of GDP and employment. You also argue that Japan has been resisting Americanisation ever since the nineteenth century. I actually think the opposite is the case. Walk down any street in Tokyo and you will find McDonalds and Starbucks. Men wear Italian suits; women sport the latest Luis Vuitton bags. The CD shops are filled with Michael Jackson CDS (his death made major news here). Book stores have whole floors dedicated to learning the English language. Even the Japanese language has coined new words from English. A funny one doing the rounds at the moment is 'ara saa' -- a contraction of 'araundo saa-tii" -- meaning "around thirty" (women in their early thirties or late twenties). Anyway, this is a brief response to your feedback on my article. I would encourage you write a more detailed response on your website or as a letter-to-the-editor. I think it is invaluable that Queenslanders have centres and organisations dedicated to furthering policy discussion and debate. |
Email sent 20/9/09 |
Email to Leon Wolff sent 20/9/09 Thanks for feedback. It is good to see someone working at understanding Japan. However I suggest that doing this is not as easy as your response implies. There is an old joke about an Irish farmer who, when asked the way to Dublin, said: 'You can't get there from here'. In some ways the same applies to your journey because you can't get to an understanding of Japan on the basis of the classical Greek thought which is the basis of Western methods for problem solving (via rationality) and social organisation (eg via law). You suggested that bureaucrats can't control the economy because no 'law' authorises them to do so. However Confucianism (which is the basis for bureaucratic governance traditions in East Asia) is a system of inter-personal relationships without any concept of law. Moreover bureaucracies (comprising the top performers in the education system) are the top of the Confucian pecking order and have effectively controlled countries like China and Japan for thousands of years (behind the facade of emperors in the past, and political parties / 'democratic' governments now) using their superior abilities to access and manage information - and thus their ability to influence what others think. An old story concerns an invading force coming to a Chinese region - which encounters an old bureaucrat on the road who invites the invader's leader to become emperor. This suits him fine, so he is installed with great pomp and splendour and given 100 concubines to keep him amused. Periodically he decides on some law or other that he thinks should be enacted. Patiently the old bureaucrat explains why this would not work, so the new emperor (like the old one) goes back to his concubines and forgets about the complex business of government. An account of the way in which cultural traditions which are radically different to those which underpin Western societies in a section on East Asia in Competing Civilizations. This includes a brief account of how I got involved in the subject. Inventions such as law and money are useful ways of simplifying the decision-space that individuals face and have been immensely important to the progress of Western societies - because rationality (ie the notion that abstract concepts usefully model reality) only works for simple systems (see Cultural Foundations of Western Strength). The failure of rationality in complex situations is well recognised: in management theories; in public administration (in terms of the counter-intuitive responses to policy initiatives which were particularly demonstrated by Great Society experiments in the 1970s); and in the need for a market economy because of the inability of central planners to acquire the detailed information needed to make appropriate decisions. However if you reject the notion of individual decision making (and indeed the notion of individuals) because what you see is 'community' as a whole, those inventions (eg law and money) are inconsequential because there is no need to simplify issues so that individuals can decide. A few things to consider are:
I will add this exchange to my website - if this is OK with you - as I agree that the issues are important. |
Response 20/9/09 |
Email from Leon Wolff 20/9/09 I am happy to have you incorporate my original article and my emailed response as part of your analysis of Japan. Due to the urgency of other commitments, I cannot respond to your detailed comments. However, I will say this: I do not share your view of Japan as a 'Confucian' state where law, politics and economics do not assume the same significance as in the West. Anecdotes are all very nice -- so too aphorisms -- but they are no substitute for empirical analysis. Of course, culture matters (in Japan, in Australia, anywhere), but your definition of Confucianism is too lose and all-encompassing. If "all" of East Asia is Confucian, how do you explain the radically different political, legal and economic systems in Japan, China and SE Asia. Asia is far more complex and diverse than this suggests. Nevertheless, I readily accept that the Confucian angle is highly popular with some academics and most journalists. But there is a growing body of scholarly literature that contests its explanatory power. One of the more trenchant critics -- and I admit he goes too far, but he is very entertaining to read -- is J Mark Ramseyer. (See his book on Japanese Law: An Economic Approach co-authored with Nakazato.) Incidentally, law is not a Western invention; it has an equally long, if not longer history, in Chinese tradition. Just some thoughts. |
Email sent 21/9/09 |
Email sent to Leon Wolff 21/9/09 There is no doubt (as you suggested) that culture matters - and it is for this reason that 'you can't get there from here' in seeking to understand Japan (or any country in East Asia) as a state in which law, politics and economics have the same significance as in the West. The differences in assumptions about the nature of reality, knowledge, social organisation etc that I referred to must be taken into account. It was, for example, often noted in the 1980s that economists (who had a central role in public policy in Western societies) had no government role in Japan - but worked only in universities. Economists believe in understanding how an economy works. Japan's bureaucracy was involved in changing the way it worked - which is inconsistent with Western-style assumptions about the role of the natural and social sciences. I am not suggesting that Japan (or any other country) should be viewed as a 'Confucian' state. Traditional Confucianism (which involved seeking the wisdom to guide society from a study of history) failed, and was arguably responsible for China's incredibly slow adaptation to Western influences. I suspect that the key ingredient was Daoism - which was added to Confucianism to produce neo-Confucianism, and allowed a much less rigid bureaucratic approach to stimulating communitarian learning. Differences in political, legal and economic systems are not a big issue. Different nominal power structures (eg democracy or dictatorship) can be constructed on similar cultural and social frameworks, just as has been done in societies founded on Western cultural traditions. For example, while Japan's characteristic has apparently been to apply 'Asian' cultural frameworks at the level of society as a whole, China tended to do so at the level of families - so while China was equated with a 'tray of sand', Japan was seen as a 'block of stone'. Ramseyer and Nakazato's Japanese Law: An Economic Approach is interesting but not instructive. It starts (p1) by effectively assuming its conclusion (ie that Japanese and US legal traditions are similar) because it involves a study of the legal systems in isolation (ie ignoring the cultural contexts which other analysts see as important in understanding them). Moreover its understanding of economic growth theory (p2) is out of date, It suggests that growth results from creating incentives - through institutional arrangements and property rights - which channel individual efforts into productive activities. The latter is necessary but by no means sufficient. For example:
Unfortunately Ramseyer's contribution seems seriously misleading, and has the effect of reducing (rather than increase) understanding of the Japanese legal system. There is no doubt that law has a long tradition in China. There is also no doubt that it is used (by selective enforcement of regulations as Eamonn Fingleton suggested) mainly to ensure the success of activities promoted through social elites (ie those connected with the Communist Party). |