Outline
+
Addenda:
|
Outline
Australia's traditional system of government is at risk, and this
document briefly outlines various interconnected causes for concern before
speculating about a possible 'nation building' agenda.
Democratic-style government has
faced growing structural difficulties (eg the greater complexity of policy
issues often transcends simple / purely-rational prescriptions; globalization
which makes
economic intervention increasingly counter-productive, requires understanding unfamiliar cultures
and reduces governments' ability to counter social inequality; machinery has been damaged by ill-advised 'reform'; academic idealists have
undermined confidence in the tacit wisdom and practical arrangements that
have been the product of experience; and political
leaders have often responded to their difficult situation by
seeking votes on the basis of impractical populism).This has
created particular difficulties for Australia because the civil institutions
that an effective democracy requires to provide the raw material for
political debate have never been strong as a result of Australia's 'lucky
country' reliance
on: (a) natural resource wealth; (b) alliances with UK / US; and (c) ideas
developed in Western-style global institutions. As a consequence of those institutional
weaknesses there has been:
Secondly administrative support to elected
governments has been seriously weakened and made more complex
by poorly considered efforts to: (a) overcome 'bureaucratic resistance'
to the impracticality or likely unintended consequences of populist policies; and (b) address the financial constraints facing
governments through the use of methods that are not appropriate for
governments' primarily-non-business-like functions. The breakdown of effective machinery of government has been
further exacerbated by:
- Increased centralisation of control of
policies and programs which tends to result in overly-simplistic and
inappropriate policies / programs for the same reason that centralised
economic planning fails (ie an inability to access all of the required
information and the suppression of collaborative / decentralised
initiative). A major, though not the only, factor in increasing
centralization has been...
- federal - state financial imbalances
that lead to irresponsibility, buck passing, duplication and complexity,
'pork barrelling' and thus make government functions wasteful and ineffectual.
- attempted politicization of the head of state ('Crown)', whose
role as the holder of all Executive power without a political agenda and
power base is the foundation of the Constitution; and
- an emerging breakdown of the separation of 'church' and 'state' as
obstacles to human / state claims of moral authority that arise
from Judeo-Christian traditions have eroded (ie the expectation that moral interpersonal relationships
are sufficiently ensured by individual consciences responsible to God). Experience
under systems reliant on human / state claims to moral authority (ie where
communal pressure is applied to ensure conformity) suggests that
this will make it impossible to maintain the individual liberty that has been the basis of
Australia's legal and government institutions and economic system.
The resulting potential and actual governance failures and radical
changes are particularly risky at
a time when external threats seem far greater than they have for two generations
[1,
2,
3,
4,
5].
If such dysfunctions in Australia's system of government are not corrected,
then:
- the political stability that Australian's have long enjoyed
through their democratic tradition would seem
likely to be lost (eg if a breakdown in effective government leads a
disaffected community
to support authoritarians who promise solutions by suppressing disagreements);
- economic reversals and external challenges to
Australia's future can be expected.
In the context of an increasingly obvious failure of effective
governance and an unstable international environment, suggestions about a process of nation building
that might reduce these risks were added in 2010.
May 2003 (and updated in 2010)
|
Challenges to Democracy
|
CHALLENGES TO Australia's
democratic institutions
While the following discussion of problems affecting the democratic
process focuses on Australia's situation (and relies heavily on Queensland
examples), the diagnosis appears to have more general relevance.
Indicators
Democratic institutions (ie the effective power of elected representative
governments) have been under challenge for at least two decades.
Symptoms of this decline include perceptions about:
Within one party (the ALP) there has been extensive
debate about the need
for fundamental reform. It has also been suggested that solutions can not
be found through internal reform - because the real problem may be that
the national political process is losing its relevance to local
and global arenas [1]
At an international level questions
about the effectiveness of democratic institutions also include:
- loss of power by parliament in the face of globalization and autocratic
government, and the corruption of institutions for political advantage;
- the effectiveness of democracy in managing a society's collective
knowledge;
- perceived conspiracies by elites;
- suppression of rights; and
- philosophical fashions which have made it difficult to challenge autocratic
leaders
Challenges to the global dominance of Western-style democratic
capitalism also arise overtly from Islamist extremists (see
September 11: The First Test)
and covertly from trends towards the creation of an international order
based on East Asian traditions that would be incompatible with the post
WWII global order promoted under US leadership (see Creating a New International 'Confucian' Economic and Political Order?)
Another area of challenge that has yet received limited attention is the
tendency that some democratic governments have exhibited to incur large
debts - because public demands for benefits from governments that exceed
the ability of the economy to provide tax revenues have not been able to
be effectively resisted. This is a fundamental challenge because broadly
based democracy became the basis for government first in the UK at the
time of the industrial revolution, when it provided a means to
redistribute throughout society the wealth generated from the deployment
of capital. If the capacity of an economy to generate income does not
exceed a community's demands on that income through democratic
government, then something has got to give.
Causes
Several 'natural' causes can be suggested for these symptoms (eg increasing complexity;
globalization; lack of support from a competent Public Service or independent
policy institutions; post-modern cynicism; and a descent into populism).
However it is also possible (though by no means certain) that deliberate Art-of-War style subversion of Australia's system of
government (ie making 'suggestions / observations' that encourage political
leaders and / or their advisers to institute 'reforms' that have the effect
of reducing government's ability to govern effectively) may also have played a part, because
encouraging enemies to thus weaken their capabilities is simply how 'Art of War' strategies
are traditionally conducted in East Asia (see below)
Key conclusions that will emerge are that:
- increasing complexity is a fundamental challenge to the effectiveness
of 'rational' methods of problem solving (including that associated with
democratic politics) that are foundational to the strengths which Western
societies have exhibited in recent centuries (see
comment on complexity below);
- as governments' challenges
have become too complex for simple solutions to be identified, democratic
societies have tended to support political elites who unrealistically
declare that the issue is actually quite simple (eg solutions require only
(say): more moral values;
setting up a new organisation; or spending huge amounts of money) and re-engineer government machinery and other
institutions to ensure that tame 'experts' tell them what they want to hear.
This has amplified the risks that complexity poses, because it has eroded
the ability (through consensus forming and collegiality) that an effective
public service traditionally provided to enable governments to deal with the
complexity that is their major challenge (see comments
on government machinery below).
First the increasing complexity of the issues
which governments have to deal with since the 1970s has reduced their ability
to generate effective solutions.
For example:
- in the 1970s 'great society' ambitions to re-engineer societies to
overcome disadvantage were generally frustrated - a problem which analysts
often ascribed the limits to rationality ie to the counter-intuitive responses
of complex social systems to simplistic state initiatives;
- in the 1970s and 1980s the methods for managing the macro-economy
which governments had used with apparent success in the post WWII era
were no longer effective - arguably because strong feedback effects
between price increases and wages led to stagflation;
- environmental constraints emerged for which no realistic long term
solutions have yet been able to be envisaged.
- from the 1970s the pace of change in the natural, social and
political environment has accelerated. One result of this has been a
change in they way organisations are managed - specifically the
emergence of techniques
for strategic planning / management. However this pace of change
has increased complexity in the issues that have to be dealt with by
political debate - as not all perceive that familiar relationships and
assumptions can quickly go out of date
- globalization in the 1990s has introduced cultural differences as
a factor in policy and debates - which raises almost insuperable problems
because of the difficulty of effective communication across cultural boundaries
and of developing a global order able to accommodate cultural differences
(eg see The Second Failure of Globalization?);
-
poor individual behaviour resulting from a breakdown in morality has
become an increasingly important factor in social outcomes which the state
can do little that is effective to correct (see [1]
and Moral Foundations (below) and comments in
About Child Sex Abuse and
in Competing Civilizations).
This may be the origin of (a) so-called 'junk politics' which are
said to reduce state action to moralizing and symbolic gestures [1]
and (b) growing state pressure to define and enforce moral principles
which would result in the loss of the political and economic benefits
of individual liberty (see below);
-
difficulties have become obvious in planning transport options in
traditional ways (ie one element at a time) not only
because of the dependence of each element on the total transport
network, but because there is a need to simultaneously and dynamically
evaluate and manage (a) individual transport elements (b) the network
(c) the effect of a crisis in the global financial system on project
funding (d) a possible discontinuity in transport technologies and
preferences related to the global peak oil event and (e) an associated
shift in regional location choices.
Increased complexity has also made adequate public debate about some issues
very difficult, and contributed to perceptions (or the reality) of deliberate
deception of the public by political leaders [1].
For example:
The problem is not confined to national politics as attempts to
develop solutions to a global environmental challenge (climate change)
appears also to in danger of over-simplifying the problem to the point
where proposed solutions could be ineffectual and hazardous (see
Climate Change; 'No time to
lose' in doing exactly what?). Similar constraints applied to the G20's
responses from 2009 to the global financial crisis (see Too Hard for the G20?).
Complexity also appears to contribute to perception of conspiracies by
elites. Theories about 'conspiracies' seem to emerge from sources who do
not understand how political and economic affairs are conducted in practice
and thus can't say how those practices might be improved, and find it convenient
to ascribe problems to elite 'conspiracies' (see
About 'Grand Conspiracy' Theories).
Complexity poses fundamental challenges to democratic government and to
Western societies in general, because complexity renders rationality
ineffective (ie the assumption underpinning rationality that problems can be
understood in terms of simple concepts is rendered invalid).
The strength of Western societies has arguably been based on the creation
(through various means including democracy) of artificially simplified
social spaces in which rationality can be a reasonably effective means of
problem solving (see Cultural
Foundations of Western Strength). Finding means to make the problems
governments face less complex is likely to be critical to restoring
effective government (eg as suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below).
The problem is like that facing central economic planners. Economists
main justification for a market economy is that central authorities can
never acquire the complex information required to make appropriate
decisions, so it is better for governments to create a framework (ie a
market economy) through which decentralised decisions can be made by
businesses each of which face a simpler environment. The solution to the
problem of complexity in 'governing' will probably involve something
similar.
Second globalization,
which has accelerated in recent decades, has increased the difficulties
governments face. For example, economic activity has become harder for
governments to constructively influence.
Globalization of economic activity through improved transport and communication
and raising of skills in previously under-developed states has:
- increased the economic significance of international trade and investment
and the need for compliance with international standards - and thus reduced
the ability of elected governments to define rules and arrangements to
suit domestic desires;
- reduced the scope for higher tax rates on individuals or corporations
(because of the need to compete with other regimes, some of whom have
low environmental and social welfare expectations) - and thus reduced
the scope for public spending without incurring fiscal deficits and
increasing debts;
- fundamentally challenged the broadly-based
representative
democracy which emerged in the UK in the mid 19th century as one means
of ensuring a reasonable sharing of the wealth generated by capital
intensive production in industrial society. Globalization has been
associated with a general shift of capital-intensive production to
lower wage economies increased the importance of specialized market and technological knowledge
as the basis for economic competitive advantage in the post-industrial
functions that advanced economies have diversified into. This has further reduced the ability of democratic institutions (who can never
possess this specialized and constantly-changing information) to take
a constructive lead in stimulating economic change (see
Economic Solutions
appear to be Beyond Politics);
And the growing influence of economic systems that are incompatible with
international practices established on the basis of Western traditions has
contributed to: (a) global financial
imbalances and instabilities; and (b)
rising inequality.
Moreover there is no effective system of global governance and this reduces the influence of
nation states relative to the global market by enabling 'jurisdiction
shopping'. Also the current global order, which (though
unsatisfactory) is compatible with
Australia's traditional democratic capitalist institutions, could fail
under some circumstances (see The Second
Failure of Globalization? and comments below
on the potential emergence regionally of an international order based on East
Asian traditions).
Democratic governments have tried to respond to the consequences
of economic globalization by:
- reducing the role of the state [1];
or
- undertaking what Robert Reich in the 1980s identified as The Work of
Government - ie creating sound regulatory and taxation regimes to attract
business, and providing quality economic inputs (eg an educated and skilled
workforce, infrastructure, and technological infrastructure); or
- 'third way' governance
arrangements - under which it is assumed that a global market will drive the
economy and that government's should seek to compensate for the social costs
and empower the community to compete.
However none of these options provide democratic institutions with much power
to set overall directions for a community.
An equally significant, and universally ignored problem, is that
globalization has encouraged political leaders to try to act in
international arenas on the basis of domestic political paradigms in
environments in which those paradigms are much less appropriate. US
unilateralism in relation to the 'war on terror' is a notable example (see
The Second Failure of Globalization?).
The problem is that:
- cultural assumptions (and associated social institutions) are critical
factors in the ability of a society to archive material prosperity - or to
successfully adopt a system of (say) democratic capitalism (see
Competing Civilizations);
- this constraint is universally put in the 'too hard' basket and
ignored - thus creating huge potential for conflicts
Third as governments experienced
increasing difficulties changes to machinery of government (as
outlined below) have been implemented. In
particular:
- governments tended to assume that when their policy ambitions were
frustrated, the fault must lie in the administrative institutions; and
- budget constraints were seen as best resolved by making public functions increasingly market, rather than policy,
driven (eg by privatization or the adoption of 'commercial' goals).
Unfortunately, because 'reformers' were often driven by political or economic
goals and apparently had little experience of the requirements for
effective governance, such changes further reduced the effective influence
of elected governments (eg efforts to overcome 'bureaucratic resistance'
eroded the knowledge and skill base of key support institutions by
often-inadvertently installing cronies and 'yes men' in dominant position).
The key challenge facing governments is their ability to handle complexity
(see Governing is not just running a
large business). Governments' core function is 'governing' (ie creating
a framework, through a system of law and in other ways, for the social and
economic activities undertaken by the community). Undertaking this
successfully requires a huge amount of knowledge and experience. The
secondary function of government is providing goods and services that are
subject to significant market failures. The factors that lead to market
failures (ie make it impossible to successfully manage such functions
through market mechanisms) also give rise to complexity (ie to making the
management of relationships between functions as important as managing
individual elements). Traditionally governments received support in
managing complex relationships between functions through the consensus
forming processes and collegiality of professional public services. However
the latter capabilities were severely eroded by 'reforms' that were intended
to promote efficiency in the production of individual elements (see
Neglected Side Effects of national
competition policies)
Fourth, changes in epistemology (ie in
assumptions about the nature of knowledge) as reflected in (so-called) post-modern
assumptions have become pervasive in many university arts' / humanities' faculties and
influenced the way in which a generation of their students think about policy
issues. This assumption effectively denies the existence of public truth (as
claims about truth are seen to always reflect the assumptions which particular
social groups make for their own political advantage).
In practice asserting that all claims about 'truth' are subjective leads
to many real-world dysfunctions (eg practical knowledge and experience have
been devalued resulting in reduced institutional capabilities and 'taboos' have
emerged on the study of some critical, especially cross-cultural, issues - see
Eroding the West's Foundations).
Furthermore these assumptions imply that any statement of public policy or attempt
to debate policy, which are foundational components of democratic governance,
must be almost meaningless.
In the absence of agreement about 'public truth' real democratic governance
is essentially impossible, and national cohesion probably requires some sort
of social hierarchy (as has been the East Asian tradition because of adherence
to 'truth-denying' epistemologies - see 'Asia'
Literacy).
Finally in the absence of viable solutions, the democratic process has
tended to install populist governments - those which
speak of solutions which are:
- trendy enough to bluff the media and other elites (who carry public opinion) though they
lack practical substance (see Towards Good
Government in Queensland and
Queensland's Challenge
which outlines the ongoing 'nightmare' that resulted
from a lack of practical competence in attempting to implement the
'dreams' of Queensland elites);
or
- out-of-date but based on public understanding of what is believed to have
worked in the past; or
- focused on easy-to-understand 'projects' rather than the policies required
for systemic solutions. Queensland has had a tradition of focusing on 'major
projects' which: (a) reflects the lack of top management skills in its small
business / branch office environment; (b) has been a key factor in its economic
under-development and problems in public administration (see
Management Gaps in Queensland). This 'major projects', rather than
systematic policy, focus has extended to the Federal Government through programs
such as Auslink - which essentially
guarantees
that critical problems in developing integrated transport systems will remain
unresolved.
In turn, populist governments apparently tend to rely on 'experts' who
tell them what they want to hear (ie that there are simple solutions). The
politicisation of Public Services in Australia (ie ensuring dominance by
cronies and 'yes men' illustrates this problem (see
The Growing Case for a Professional Public Service;
and
Decay of Australian Public Administration).
An attempt to define
a systematic view of the growing phenomenon
of policy populism has been developed by Steve Dovers, while the
chronic weakness of Queensland's political system can realistically be described
in terms of populism resulting from a lack of institutional support.
Some specific examples of insubstantial populism
in recent public policies include:
- the superficial assessment of strategic issues involved in Australia's
commitment to war in Iraq (see below)
- the very poor quality of debate and analysis about the possibility of
a fundamental change to the the central institution of Australia's constitution
in the 'republic' debate. Despite popular support for changing Australia's
head-of-state system. A model was presented to a referendum which did not meet public desired for a 'directly elected' presidential system.
Moreover advocates of that model seemed unable to explain to the electorate
why the popular model would be inconsistent with stability
and effectiveness under Australia's system of government.
Also
a republican model for Australia based on a populist 'directly elected' president
was reportedly advocated by a potential Prime Minister on the grounds that
this was the only way to 'wedge' his political opponents [1];
- methods envisaged to develop Australia's innovation capabilities by increasing
the supply of 'smart' inputs (eg education and research) without seriously
upgrading capabilities to profit from those inputs (see
The Economic Futility of Backing Australia's Ability 2
and
Commentary on Smart State). The application of those policies has
accompanied the rapid decline in Australia's innovation ranking;
- focusing on 'children overboard' or playing the 'racism card' in relation to problems in dealing with unauthorized
migration which involved far more complex issues (see
Complexities in the Refugee Problem);
- the focus on greenhouse gas emissions as the source of climate change
and the assumption that aggressive action to reduce this would have only
minor costs (see Finding
the Truth on Climate Change).
Other examples that arose in the context of Australia's 2007 federal
election campaign are cited in
On Populism while those that provided a
backdrop to the 2010 federal election are mentioned
below. Traditionally
political populism meant that governments could do little good, but the
existence of a professional public service ensured that populists'
wild imaginings were subject to a reality check which limited the
damage that could be done . Now unfortunately, politicisation of public
services means that populism can potentially be extremely damaging to the
public interest - and scope has been created for the election of persons who
might be, in effect, mere confidence tricksters.
Australia's Reliance on 'Luck'
These increasing difficulties facing democratic
governments generally have been compounded by Australia's traditional 'lucky
country' status, and the consequent lack of adequate support for institutions
that are critically important for effective democracy.
Democratic political systems are critically dependent on the existence of strong
civil institutions (eg universities, research institutes,
associations) able to provide quality ideas for policy debate, and
on support in policy development and implementation by a competent civil
service.
As noted below, public
services in Australia have been weakened by ill-informed efforts to
'reform' them.
However Australia's civil institutions have always been weak because Australia
depended on the 'luck' of rich resources and copying policy initiatives from
leading OECD societies and global institutions that are based on compatible
Western principles. This chronic institutional weakness (which results amongst other
things in poor general community understanding of the nature and functions
of government) reflects the general tendency of resource
dependent economies, such as Australia's to raise up political and business elites who
rely on resource wealth rather than providing economic leadership (see
About the Curse of Natural
Resources;
Queensland's Weak
Parliament and
Comments on Australia's
Economic Under-development).
Furthermore shifts in society towards the 'radical individualism' that apparently
characterized many political activists of the baby boomer (and later) generations is
likely to have further eroded effective participation in the civil institutions
on whose contributions the democratic process depends.
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below
|
Strategy |
INADEQUATE INTELLIGENCE AND STRATEGIC ASSESSMENT
There has been a serious weakness in Australia's ability to assess its national
strategic interests (eg because of weak domestic institutions and reliance
on external leadership).
This was clearly revealed, for example, by the public debate concerning weapons
of mass destruction (WMD) as the basis for participating in military action
in Iraq in 2003.
An evaluation of the strategic environment related to the problem of
dealing with the risk of terrorists with WMD strongly suggests that the
US's strategic response linked to regime change in Iraq was based on very
complex considerations (eg see speculations in
The Second Failure of Globalization?).
In brief: key issues that apparently needed to be explored
in the background to that situation include:
- the political and economic failure of numerous states, a problem
that has many causes and gives rise threats to neighbours and to
global society;
- the loss of confidence in multilateral action by the US, which
had originally sponsored and long supported that system, and the
emergence of proposals for unilateral US action
However in Australia there appear to be no governmental or independent
institutions able to make and communicate such assessments to the public
- or even to the government (though one observer pointed out that advice
may have come behind the scenes from PM&C, DFAT and Defence Departments
[1])
Prior to Australia's commitment to the campaign in Iraq, the public case
for regime change was based only on its WMD programs - though this issue
was probably only a 'marketing' tool (noting Paul Wolfowitz's
remarks suggesting that it was the focus because it was the only thing
everyone agreed about. And even after the event, the
assessment of the case for participation (by a parliamentary committee and
the media) focused only on weaknesses in intelligence about the WMD issue
and those institutions proved entirely incapable of addressing Australia's
strategic interests generally (see
Strategic Assessment).
This is particularly significant in that it appears that the strategy being
pursued by the US administration, whose lead Australia has followed, was flawed (again see The Second Failure of
Globalization?).
In brief: It seemed that the hidden-agenda of the 'Neo-Cons'
(who held sway in determining the US's response to the 911 attacks,
because they appeared to be the only ones with any serious proposals) was to take
pre-emptive action to avert the risk of a major future war (ie one that
could emerge following likely Islamist revolutions against bad
governments throughout the Middle East) by creating in Iraq a successful
model of political economy that might be emulated across the region.
However that aspiration arguably involved unrealistic assumptions about
the prospect of successfully creating such a regime in Iraq (because the
cultural and institutional preconditions for such a regime could never
be created through the use of 'hard power'). However this was never considered because the nominal goal of dealing with WMD was all
that was publicly mentioned, and students of the humanities were off on
a postmodern 'trip' involving the belief that cultural assumptions had
no practical consequences.
Another example of apparently inadequate intelligence and strategic
assessment involves the imbalances in the global financial system (see
Structural
Incompatibility Puts Global Growth at Risk) which apparently
closely relate to the challenge that East Asia's neo-Confucian styles of
governance poses to the democratic capitalist style of global order that
Western societies have established in recent centuries (see
East Asia in Competing
Civilizations).
Similarly economic policies (such as the National Competition Policy)
seemed to be derived primarily on the basis of academic theories
without closely studying changes in the
international environment which may render those theories inadequate.
A significant decline in the ability of Australia's overseas representatives
to access and assess information has also been suggested [1],
as has a lack of reliance on systematic professional advice in relation to the
commitment to intervention of Iraq. [1]
It is noteworthy that Daniel Ellsberg showed how intelligence presented to
the US government about the Vietnam war could be distorted to meet political
expectations and then used to justify pre-formed assumptions about desirable
strategic policies [1].
Australia at that time would have been less likely to have been susceptible
to such 'group think' because it had a professional Public Service who could
safely express independent opinions. However politicisation in recent years
has presumably reduced this protection.
The problem of identification
/ protection of the national strategic interest is complicated by exposure to
rising powers in East Asia whose strategic methods and means for exerting power
are radically different to those of Western societies (eg see
below).
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below
|
Lack of
Asia Literacy |
LACK OF ASIA LITERACY
It is of particular significance that there is very limited understanding of the challenges to
Australia's system of government that are implicit in the rapid progress
being achieved under neo-Confucian styles of government, as goals and
strategic methods are radically different in societies with an ancient
Chinese heritage, rather than the West's Judeo-Christian and classical Greek heritage (see
East Asia
in Competing Civilizations and 'Asia'
Literacy).
In brief: In East Asia abstract ideas are not regarded as reliable, so
methods for problem solving and managing change have been created that do
not depend on individual rationality or political debate.
For example, power in Asia is equated, not with making decisions as
Australia's citizens and political elites expect to do, but rather with having social
subordinates who make decisions for the powerful.
Such societies tend to act as a whole, rather than as a collection of
individuals.
This is significant because, for
example:
-
the problem of complexity that now
bedevils Western approaches to political power is dealt with differently, and
this is one of the reasons that:
-
the obstacles to authorities in guiding faster economic
development are less severe than in Western societies - so economic
real-economy 'miracles' are achieved while national savings are used
irresponsibly;
-
the civilizational 'clash' with East Asia seems more
significant than that with Islamist extremists. A prominent Japanese bureaucrat argued,
for example, that the complexities of social and environmental issues would,
in fact, destroy the idea of 'progress', which has been the unique and
characteristic goal of Western societies [1];
-
China (Australia's biggest trading partner) seemed in 2016 to be
facing a major financial, economic and political crisis that many
observers could not understand (see
Importing Risks from China);
-
power is exerted by providing information
to influence others' thinking rather than more directly; 'war' is fought
through deception and encouraging others' to weaken their position rather
than by overt opposition; and ethnic business / organised crime combine
with governments in pursuit of nationalistic goals (see
Art of War). In 2016
there was evidence of the use by China's regime of 'soft power' methods to
manipulate Australia's academic, political and economic institutions - in
much the same way as that regime maintains power in China (see
Chinese Influence in Australia, Debating
the Australia - China Relationship and
What is Soft Power? );
-
Australia's
weak strategic intelligence gathering and assessment
capabilities make it vulnerable.
Examples of the impact of such methods seemed to have emerged in the 1980s
in relation to the influence of apparently-ultranationalist Japanese groups on Queensland's political economy.
The implications of these challenges is speculated more comprehensively
in documents listed in
CPDS' Documents on the Challenge of Asian Authoritarianism (eg China as the 'Future of the
World'?, An
Unrecognised Clash of Financial Systems?,
Understanding East Asia's
Neo-Confucian systems of socio-political-economy, Creating a New International 'Confucian' Economic
and Political Order?, Some
Thoughts on the China Era,
Comments
on Australia's Strategic Edge in 2030 and Babes in the Asian
Woods). The latter includes examples of
the risks that Australia faces as a consequence of Asia-illiterate opinion
leaders and decision makers - including:
- misunderstanding the origins of the global financial crisis, and the
role that non-capitalistic financial systems in East Asia: (a) played in
generating the international financial imbalances that contributed to that
crisis; and (b) could play in future in causing East Asian systems of
socio-political-economy to fail;
- establishing a regime for taxation of Australia's mineral resources
that could significantly reduce the revenues Australian governments gain
because differences between the character of East Asian and Western
systems of political economy were not understood..
- the possibility of encouraging
political actions which have the effect of 'hollowing out' the practical
competence of Australia's institutions (eg by politicisation of public
services);
- misunderstanding Australia's geo-political interests.
Very substantial strengthening of support to
Australia's democratic
institutions may be required, if they are to remain viable in such an
environment. See remedies suggested in
A Nation Building Agenda below
|
Public
Administration |
Weakening
administrative support
Since at least the late 1980s Governments have been tending towards ineffectual
or risky populism - a problem that was mentioned above
(and is also considered separately in the
Decay of Australian Public Administration
and
On Populism).
This partly reflects a decline in the ability of
Public Services to competently support executive governments in policy development
and implementation as a result both of the politicisation / de-skilling of senior
appointments and of attempts to remodel governments as pseudo 'businesses' in
order to hopefully gain better value for money by increasing production efficiency.
National Competition Policy appears to have had a role in weakening administrative
support to government because the side-effects of seeking to apply business-like
methods to fundamentally non-business-like functions were not considered (see
Review of National Competition Policy Reforms: A
Commentary). The goal of those methods was to boost economic
productivity through raising the production efficiency of such functions and
their responsiveness to demand. What was clearly not recognised was the
limitations of bottom-line criteria to many public functions (see
The Advantages
and Limitations of Financial Criteria).
Breaking down their administrative support has led some political leaders
to:
- be seen to be arrogant - perhaps because, having surrounded themselves
with cronies and 'yes men', they do not understand the need to communicate
with segments of the community who do not share their assumptions;
- experience sudden electoral reversals (see
The Origin and
Spread of the Queensland Effect);
- apologize constantly for administrative failings to avoid the perception
of arrogance [1];
- be seen to be good at nothing but winning elections [1].
In the process of 'reform' the dominant goal of Public Services shifted
from helping the public by ensuring good government, to helping the government
of the day to retain political power.
It has been suggested that it is a major problem
that senior civil servants are no longer useful sources of policy
advice - as:
-
the success of democratic models (and the reason they did not turn
into the 'mob-ocracy which opponents feared when universal suffrage was granted)
was because of the political and cultural role of the senior civil servants
[1];
-
the strong influence that pseudo market / commercial 'solutions' have had on
public services has tended to leave them dominated by 'econocrats' whose
advice is likely to be inappropriate in ways that are not widely perceived (The
Advantages and Limitations of Financial Criteria);
-
as noted above the
loss of the steadying wisdom of experience that used to be provided by professional public services now makes it possible for political
populists to do massive harm to the public interest, in ways that were not
possible in the past.
It has also become essentially
impossible to manage the delivery of public goods and services as a whole, because
they involve functions that can not be coordinated satisfactorily through market
mechanisms. The latter problem is illustrated particularly by emerging concerns
about infrastructure deficiencies (see
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy).
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below
|
Centralisation |
CENTRALISATION A drift towards more
centralised control of policy and programs has been apparent for decades as
a result of both: (a) chronic fiscal imbalances within Australia's federal
system - see below; and (b) political
frustration with the apparent inability of traditionally less centralised
machinery to respond to emerging challenges.
The initiative of rational
/ responsible individuals has been the primary source of strength in Western societies.
This works well in organisational settings which have been created (eg by a
rule of law or a reliance on profitability in resource allocation) to
present problems that are relatively uncomplicated / understandable and where incremental
initiative accumulates into effective system wide responses (See
Cultural Foundations of Western
Strength: The Realm of the Rational / Responsible Individual).
Functions that governments undertake tend to be: (a) 'governing' (ie
creating a framework in which others can 'do things'); and (b) the provision
of goods and services that can't be undertaken through competitive market
processes - because decentralised incremental initiative is frustrated by
very significant externalities (ie inter-relationships amongst different
functions, or the absence of any workable market mechanism) - see also
Governing is not Just Running a Large
Business. The traditional processes of public administration can be
reasonably effective in dealing with the complexity that governments have
faced (eg through promoting collegiality and consensus amongst those dealing
with interconnected functions).
However, as noted above, the issues that
governments confront have become significantly more complex (ie interconnected)
and rapidly changing - and this
has tended to reduce the effectiveness of public functions. And in recent
decades politicisation and attempts to apply market mechanisms to public
functions (ie those subject to significant externalities or market failures)
has further eroded the ability of traditional public administration methods
to handle complexity.
Centralisation (eg by federal attempts to control functions that are
state responsibility; by establishing strong policy capabilities in
ministerial / cabinet / chief executive offices; or by merging agencies; or
by establishing centralised 'super-departments') has been one method used in
an attempt to bypass complexity (eg the strong relationships that any public
function will tend to have with other functions and / or within particular
regions) by imposing simple solutions that sound plausible to those who
don't have any deep / realistic understanding of the situation.
However centralising control of government functions is not an
effective solution - see also
Centralization is Part of the Problem:
Not the Solution. Trying to ignore complexity does not make that
complexity go away. Thus administrative centralisation faces the same
fundamental obstacles as attempting centralised control of an economy.
Central economic planning has long been recognised to fail because
'authorities' can never acquire all the necessary information / knowledge /
experience / initiative / commitment. They thus tend to support actions that
don't meet real economic demands. The same applies to centralised control of
government policies and programs.
And as noted below attempts to
simplify issues through federal government micro-management of state
functions on the basis of Australia's federal fiscal imbalances dramatically
distorts / complicates the performance of those functions. The obstacles to
effective management of public functions have been further increased by
politicisation of public services - as this tends
to have the effect of eliminating experience-based understanding of the
complexities involved without actually eliminating the complexities
themselves.
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below |
Federalism |
Federal - State
Fiscal Imbalances
A critical source of weakness in Australia machinery of government that has been growing for decades
has been that the federal system has concentrated tax powers / revenues in the federal government
and responsibility for service delivery in state administrations (including
local government).
This imbalance appears to have come about largely,
but not only,
because over the past 70 years the High Court (which lacks the technical ability
to fully evaluate the economic, public finance or public administration effect
of its decisions - and has always been appointed by Commonwealth ministers)
has concentrated ever increasingly fiscal capacity in the Commonwealth Government
[1].
Fiscal imbalances have been a major driver (though not the only driver -
noting that states had surrendered their income tax powers during WWII) of the drift towards
centralisation mentioned above both across the
federal-state interface and within states. Interest groups have presumably
often sought
'national' action to deal with their agendas partly because the Commonwealth
Government was seen to
have much stronger sources of revenue.
Financial imbalance have had a practical impact on government in
Australia through the provision of large amounts of special purpose funding
which escalated from the 1970s (as
noted
below). This has seriously distorted public administration over many decades. Consequences include: irresponsibility, buck passing,
duplication and complexity, 'pork barrelling'. Government functions have
been rendered relatively wasteful and ineffectual.
Dysfunctional consequences of fiscal imbalances have
included:
- the expansion in special purpose funding (especially in the 1970s).
This appeared
to reduce the ability of states to perform their functions effectively because
it: (a) reduced their ability to make decisions and funding commitments; (b)
forced
states to concentrate more on lobbying for federal
approval than on the requirements of their functions;
and (c) shifted internal decision making within states to central intergovernmental-relations and financial staffs
and away from those with the tacit / technical knowledge of what is required
and whose commitment / initiative was vital to producing effective /
efficient outcomes.
Using the 'power of the purse' to achieve 'national' strategic goals
necessarily results in less efficiency and effectiveness, and (in
effect) significantly reduces the value of that 'purse'. The overall effect
has been somewhat like that of tariff protection on corporate managements, or welfare
dependence on the disadvantaged. The weakening of state
administrative capacities may have been a factor in the
decline in public capital investment in the 1980s and 1990s to levels
well below OECD norms - and the consequent backlogs which many observers
now identify (see also
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy);
- there is a problem in accountability and political motivation because
the federal government carries the political cost of raising revenue - while
the states get many political benefits out of spending it. The federal government
is now constantly forced to try to refute accusations of being a high taxing
government (despite the fact that Australians overall tax burden is less
than in many developed countries) because taxes collected on behalf of the
states (eg GST) are labelled as federal taxes. Moreover one observer has
suggested that very rapid growth in state spending has arisen because states
are not responsible for revenue raising [1];
- states, who have responsibility for economic development, have had limited
financial incentive to take development of productive modern economies seriously
- because Commonwealth payments are states' most important revenue sources
and these tend to be distributed 'equitably' irrespective of the weakness
or strength of a state's tax base (see
Comment on Review of Grants Commission
Arrangements and [1]).
This disincentive has probably significantly lowered:
- Australia's overall economic performance (noting that Australia's
per capita GDP had been in more-or-less constant decline relative to international
standards ever since federation - though this trend changed in the 1990s);
- aggregate tax revenues available to Australia's public sector;
- attempts by the federal government to micromanage nominally state
functions have further eroded the effectiveness of Australia's overall
system of government through reducing community access to understanding
of complex public policy issues, and thus reducing the effectiveness of
the democratic process (eg see
TEQSA: Will Micromanagement Again Triumph over Government?);
- public functions are not always performed effectively because of divided
responsibility and conflicts. For example:
- the federal government finds itself with too much revenue and hands
back its large revenue surplus in the form of tax cuts, while the states
struggle to provide essential services with limited income. [1]
- 'pork barrelling' has emerged as a feature of federal election
campaigning in 2013 [1].
Random 'major projects' seemed to be promised in various electorates
that may or may not make sense from a local / regional viewpoint
There have been increasing signs that these fundamental
defects in the federal system are being recognized - and leading to power
struggles which further debilitate Australia's governance. For example:
- the problem of fiscal imbalance has been analysed [1];
- disputes have emerged about the financing of state functions - see
below;
- the Commonwealth has adopted a coercive (rather than a cooperative)
approach to Australia's federal system [1,
2,
3] (similar to that of
the Whitlam government in the 1970s?). In particular:
- it has been suggested that the Commonwealth has adopted a highly centralist
approach because it believes that the states (a) are incompetent and (b)
have a role purely as service deliverers - which does not give them any
role in development of policy [1]
- the federal government is seen to be interfering in state areas of responsibility
because it can make no progress in dealing with its own, and can thus avoid
responsibility [1]
- an end to commonwealth / state fighting has been seen as necessary to
allow progress in dealing with key issues [1];
- despite access to GST states have never had worse access to own-source
revenues and community has yet to grasp the significance of this for state
service delivery or state tax reform.[1]
- the incompetence which state governments have demonstrated in performing
their functions has led to community support for their abolition - though
this would be constitutionally impossible and would not actually solve the
problem [1]
- federal prescriptive control over universities has been sought by extreme
interpretation of the 'trading corporations' power, and seems likely to
further reduce the already weak ability of Australia's universities to provide
the substantial contribution to public affairs required for an effective
political process [1];
- proposals have been put forward for a federal government take-over of
responsibility of all health services [1];
- micro-economic reform has been increased national centralization of
regulation. Now national bureaucrats impose penalties on state governments
if they make electorally-endorsed decisions that are seen to be inappropriate.
States have passed over responsibility to get someone to blame when things
go wrong. There would be benefits in diversity - where outcomes would respond
to local circumstances. [1]
- reform of the federal system is seen to be vital to overcoming problems
affecting the health system. [1]
- Federal and state governments increasingly recognize the need for health
systems to be operated by a single level of government [1]
- attempts to erode the federal system have been seen to damage Australia's
constitution which has provided a century of political stability that few
other countries experienced by (a) removing a key balance of power and (b)
preventing regional issues being dealt with mainly by affected regional
communities [1]
- proposals have emerged for changing financial arrangements and rationalizing
functions [1,
2,
3,
4], resulting in no
agreement [1];
- some see solutions to confusion and duplication associated with federal
system to lie in increasing Commonwealth regulatory authority. But it has
shown an equal or greater ability to generate complex systems.[1]
- there is a need to make states accountable by letting them raise their
own revenue [1];
- states have argued that the national competition agreement has been
torn up, while health and education have not been able to be discussed in
COAG [1];
- the establishment of an effective national electricity market is at
risk from intergovernmental tensions [1]
- state's could respond by a High Court challenge in relation to industrial
relations, and by simultaneously re-establishing their own income tax regime
[1]
- states threatened continuance of national agreement assigning corporations
powers to the commonwealth if the Treasurer challenges their access to GST
revenues [1]
- the PM indicated an intention to pursue what he saw as the national
interest - over-riding the states if this was necessary [1]
- the federal government is seen as seeking to destroy the remaining functions
of states - which would not be in its interest as it would then be held
responsible for, and have to deal with, all problems that arise [1]
- the federal government is seen to be ignoring the constitutional limits
on its powers (using its financial dominance) on the grounds that states
are inefficient - yet part of that problem arises from Commonwealth duplication
of their functions [1]
- federal government efforts to take control of ports could create a very
complex regulatory and administrative environment, and disputes with the
states about this would not be in the national interest [1]
- Commonwealth attempts to control everything are seen to be a risk to
the nation as a whole [1]
- Australia's federal system now makes the states helpless - mainly because
of centralized financial power. However this is quite contrary to the intent
of the Constitution and was put in place by decisions of High Court - not
by voters .[1]
- Australia's dysfunctional federal state system needs to be overhauled
- to allow greater integration of the health system. [1]
- the federal system is a blockage to good government, and there is a
need for a summit to decide how power and money should be divided [1]
- highly centralised federal control of state grants was suggested to
potentially result in 'set-up costs' equal to the grant [1]
- NSW treasurer suggested that costs of greying population could create large funding problems
- which required an overhaul of federal / state funding arrangements [1]
- The division of responsibility for health between federal and state governments
was seen as the biggest biggest
obstacle to reforms [1]
- Australia has one of the best systems of government in the
democratic world, and its federal system is worth preserving [1]
- NSW is to host a national summit on ways to reform Australia's
fiscal system - to address report which identified a gap between states'
revenue raising powers and spending responsibilities. [1]
- a High Court decision, related to use of corporations power, appears to allow
the Commonwealth to seek control of virtually anything [1],
which must massively compounds the dysfunctions that have grown in Australia's
system of government as a result initially of the removal of state income tax powers during WWII.
- the federal system was seen to be 'broken' (noting duplication; inefficiency;
unnecessary red
tape; sub-standard services; and conflicts over control). A special constitutional convention
could be the way to fix this [1]
Moreover these distortions may now become unsustainable because of what appears
to be a potential imbalance between aggregate public revenues and expectations
about public spending.
Though this issue has not been systematically
evaluated, reasons to suspect that a problem is emerging in raising revenues
to meet public service expectations include:
- constraints and demands on federal revenues have increased, including:
- disputes have arisen about financing public expectations
in key state functions such as:
- public health services [1,
2]. As a result concern
has been expressed as the result of a Health Care Summit about the effect
of overlapping responsibility on services effectiveness, and about cost-shifting
between different levels of government [1].
An inability to address health system problems because of disputes over
financing has also been identified [1];
- water supplies - where shortages are looming in many localities [1]
;
- tertiary education [1];
- roads [1];
- state taxes [1]
- the federal government (it has been claimed) is seeking to force states
to pay more of the cost of essential services generally [1];
- signs are emerging (in spite of the revenue surge from a property boom)
of a revenue / spending imbalance in the 'growth' state of Queensland which
probably can not be reduced simply by tax rises (see
Growing Pressure for Increased Taxation). NSW appears to
be experiencing the start of a chronic financing problem [1].
And NSW and other major states have found it necessary to express concern
about the revenues they lose because of Commonwealth transfer payments (see
Comment on Review of Grants Commission
Arrangements).
At the same time that these pressures were developing, Commonwealth revenues
surged into large surpluses as a result of rapid economic growth associated
with a resource investment boom [1]
- a phenomenon which seemed unlikely to be sustainable (see
The Potential for Economic Instability).
In 2014 it seemed likely that the 'magic pudding' that federal revenues
had been seen to be was likely to be exhausted (see
Restoring The Viability of Democratic
Capitalism). The federal government (and interest groups) then started
pressuring other levels of government to take more fiscal responsibility.
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below
|
Judiciary |
Political biases in the
Judiciary
Erosion of the political independence of the Judiciary also seems to have
undermined Australia's machinery of government.
The technical competence of the Judiciary is critical to the administration
of law (and to Australia's reputation as a place to do business in particular),
while Judicial independence is vital to safeguard citizens against abuses of
executive power.
Numerous
allegations,
whose validity the author has no way to assess, now suggest that the quality
and legal competence of the Judiciary is being compromised by appointments based
on political rather than merit criteria - in a manner similar to that which
has undermined effective public administration.
It has also been argued
that politically-motivated decisions within the Judiciary have had the
effect of subverting decisions by parliament that reflected the will of a
democratic majority.
|
Head of
State
|
Politicization of the 'Crown'
Similar damage seems to have been done through efforts to politicise the
role of the head of state.
Under Australia's current constitution the
Governor General and state Governors (on behalf of the 'Crown') carry all the power of
executive governments, and make it available for use by the democratically elected
governments. The effectiveness of representative democracy has now been
de-stabilized and seriously damaged by politicization of the 'Crown', as:
- a Governor General used the position to advocate a particular political
agenda [1,
2], and continued doing
so after leaving the position [1,
2]. A state governor has
announced an intention to pursue a similar practice [1]
. In 2009 a new Governor General also took a public political position [1].
In late 2013 a Governor General continued this destabilizing practice by
taking a partisan political position (ie by advocating that Australia
become a
republic and endorse gay marriage) [1];
- the Federal Opposition leader broke the convention which had treated the
Governor General as being outside of the political game [1];
- a Governor General (G-G) resigned in the face of populist pressure involving
allegations, a flawed Church inquiry,
a biased media campaign, opinion polls, a Senate resolution
[1] which also breached constitutional
conventions and a weak Federal Government - pressure which one observer described
as the worst case of 'trial by media' since the case of Lindy Chamberlain
and which ultimately led to a virtual political 'assassination'; and
- similar 'media frenzy' seemed likely to follow any other appointment of
a Governor General - thus discouraging good people from being prepared to
take the position [1].
Ensuring that in future the holder of this office should be a person who
has popular support (or perhaps even has a definite political agenda has
been the major motive of various campaigns [1,
2, 3,
4, 5,
6,
7]. One legal observer implied
that political support was a vital requirement of the position [1].
However politicisation of this position (ie requiring popular support, and
a political agenda / networks) is totally incompatible with Australia's existing
constitutional system [1,
2] and would lead to instability
and / or abuses of power unless preceded by a referendum to appropriately change
the constitution. Even thoughtlessly subjecting this institution to populist
pressure has damaged Australia's system of government.
Constitution Origins
Australia's constitution was derived at the start of the 20th century from
the system of governance that existed in Britain at that time.
That system was the product of a long period of evolution whereby the power
and privileges which monarchs had acquired through through military leadership
were shared first with a military 'nobility' and ultimately, in the mid 19th
century, with the broad mass of the community through a system of representative
democracy.
This steady transfer of power from military to civil authorities involved
the emergence of a constitutional monarchy under which eventually:
- the Crown delegated power to make laws to an elected Parliament, and the
power to interpret the law in civil, criminal and administrative matters to
an independent Judiciary;
- an executive government was formed by the party with the majority support
of a democratically elected Parliament;
- the Crown retained all the executive power of the state, but agreed not
to use this for their own purposes and to act on advice from the head of the
government; and
- the Crown oversaw the government's day-to-day actions to ensure that they
complied with the constitution.
In Australia's version of this system the British 'Crown' was represented
by a Governor General (or Governor in the case of the states).
Apart from ceremonially 'planting trees', the role which the G-G used to
play was to enable the democratically elected government to govern by exercising
the same restraint in the use of executive power as the British Crown.
Putting Political Stability at Risk
A G-G who has their own political power base and agenda will either be a
political supporter of the elected government or an opponent.
If they are an opponent then they may make it difficult at the very
least for the elected government to govern [1].
It can be noted that the Constitution allocates all executive power to the
Governor General and does not even mention the Prime Minister. Those powers
include vetoing legislation. With an independent political mandate a Governor
General would be able to oppose the will of Parliament and claim that they
were acting in the people's interests in doing so [1]
The constitutional crises that are likely to emerge where an elected
head of state had their own political agenda, power base and electoral
mandate can be illustrated by the 1975 sacking of the Whitlam Government
by the then Governor General. Whilst the Governor General was presumably
acting to resolve what was seen as a constitutional crisis related to the
blocking of supply, the fact is that the 'sacking' was: (a)
political popular - as illustrated by the large subsequent voter
preference for a change in government; and (b) widely seen itself as a
constitutional crisis.
With a popularly elected Head of State, conflicts between the latter
and the also-elected but-less-powerful government would presumably be a
regular event, and shatter Australia's reputation for political stability.
On the other hand, if they are of the same political persuasion, then the
scope for autocratic power to emerge will be huge as:
- the same faction would have control of the legislature, the executive
government and the reserve powers of the 'Crown' (which could be interpreted
as being almost unlimited); and
- the judiciary, whose independent powers are delegated from the Crown,
might have limited ability to act as a counterbalancing force.
The author recalls a paper (but can no longer locate it) which argued out
that countries who had political head of states separate from governments
tended to have periodic revolutions.
A Vice Regal Assassination?
The political 'assassination' of an incumbent G-G has undermined and exposed
the rickety foundations of the institutional core of Australia's constitution
(and this may well have been the intention of the campaign) - but has not shown
how to create a solid foundation. It seem certain to impact on whether Australia
emerges as a future republic. It might
result in either:
- future G-Gs who have their own popular / political agendas - and thus
contribute to political instability until a re-written Australian constitution
is approved at a referendum (see below); or
- damage to the republican goal of making
the position of Governor General into one that requires popular support -
if the attacks on Peter Hollingworth as G-G are eventually shown to have been
unjust thus demonstrating that (a) popular opinion can
be misled especially if the subject is not an experienced politician and (b)
any experienced politician could be unable to provide the apolitical attitude
the Governor General's constitutional role requires.
Practical
Options
Presumably Australia could seek to have an elected
G-G who has a political agenda, but for stability and to protect against autocratic
power it would then seem desirable to rearrange a large number of other aspects
of the constitution - perhaps to something like the US system where the executive
and the head of state are combined but separated from the legislature.
Implications?
Adopting a US style system in Australia would seem
likely to:
- increases the intensity and sophistication of political debate because
both the executive and legislature would presumably be well resourced
to support policy research - which would seem highly desirable given the
deplorable standards that have emerged as
administrative
machinery has been politicized; and
- encourage a much 'smaller' role for governments - because (a) under
British Law the state does not seek to represent the community as a whole
as in European (Roman) Law traditions and (b) the separation of executive
and legislature would inhibit the coordination required for governments
to play a strong interventionist role.
Interestingly it appears that Prince Charles as king might guarantee
Australia's transition to a republic because his reported desire to speak
out about public policy issues - rather than continuing the traditional
practice of doing so only in private [1]
- would seem very likely to destroy the apolitical character of the British
monarchy and thus its constitutional usefulness in the UK and elsewhere.
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below
|
Eroding
the Moral Foundations
of Australia's Liberal Institutions
|
Eroding the Moral foundations
of Australia's liberal Institutions
More subtle, but ultimately potentially more serious, damage has been
done through eroding the social foundations of the individual liberty that is built
into legal, governmental and economic institutions that Australia inherited from the
UK .
For something like 1000 years in Western societies, a deeply-embedded 'love-others' / 'value-others-as-oneself'
ethical ideal which derived from Christ-ian traditions has seemed to be a settled
basis for a morality driven by individual consciences responsible to God
(rather than by state / communal pressure to conform) - and created a
phenomenon that can be called 'responsible liberty' . There is nothing
unusual about the 'golden
rule' in diverse religious and ethical traditions. What is different in
Christianity is the credible prospect of a life-beyond-death reward for
those who individually pass a next-life judgment.
'Responsible liberty' within the community allowed a separation between affairs of state and the religious basis
of that individual morality - ie it allowed / required the emergence of
'secular' states (those that dealt with everything but religion). That separation was immensely important to building
a legal system which incorporated individual liberty and thus to the economic
prosperity and strength which Western societies achieved relative to others
particularly over the past 500 years (see
Competing Civilizations and
other observers' views in
The Emergence and Advantages of Responsible Liberty).
The former argued that:
- individual liberty could became the core
of Australia's antecedent legal system in Britain, because it was
presumed that interpersonal relations would best be guided by a Christ-ian 'value-others'
ethical ideal that was deeply embedded in the consciences of individuals responsible
to God. In other words individuals generally would feel and exhibit a
sense of responsibility for the welfare of others - both directly and
through motivating and empowering them also to be responsible and seek
others' welfare. And this sense of responsibility was inbuilt in their consciences rather than
resulting from supervision by
others (eg families, communities, moral 'authorities'). The liberty this
permitted (combined with other arrangements such as a
rule of law, democracy, decentralized governance and profit-oriented investment) ultimately allowed
the emergence of social environments in which rationality could be
more useful in problem solving (because rationality tends to fail where
complexity is not reduced), and thus dramatically increased the
effectiveness of individuals in all walks of life;
- in societies without the 'responsible
liberty' derived from this 'embedded'
ethical ideal, communal, legal and governance systems invariably are
deeply involved in determining the nature of, and enforcing, moral
behaviour (eg consider traditional tribal societies, East Asia, and the
Muslim world) - and this has a major impact on scope for political /
social liberty and the economic
/ political models that can be used . Moreover;
-
government can be far more
effective in dealing with complex and constantly changing social and
economic systems, when it does not seek to do so simply on the basis of
religious principles that are meant to (and most relevantly) apply to individual behaviour.
In Australia now, increasingly serious social dysfunctions (due to the
erosion of an innate sense of ethical responsibility based on individuals'
ultimate accountability to God) and a desire to impose their own preferred ethical
principles are encouraging would-be authoritarians (eg what could be
called the 'church' of political correctness) to
supervise individuals' behaviour - thus undermining the liberal social
foundations that are needed for liberal legal, governmental and economic
institutions.
Evidence of a Problem
Challenges
to the 'Christ-ian' philosophical and theological foundations of Western societies
and an apparent decline in churches' willingness and ability to proclaim the
Christian gospel
appear to be having significant effects.
Illustrations:
-
though popular media (such as TV and the Internet) can encourage an
overwhelming emphasis on individual self-interest
many churches seem unwilling to warn against moral offences
or to point out what is at stake in choices about religious adherence, eg everlasting life [1]
- which have been fundamental features of Christian adherence.
Christianity's founder, Jesus of Nazareth, set people free of religious
legalism (ie concern for complex human interpretations of the 'spirit' of laws
given to early prophets), but in doing so he raised the moral standard
beyond what could be expected of unaided human beings and drew attention
to the latter's exposure to ultimate judgment. The liberty that
Christianity enabled people to enjoy must create risks to the society as
a whole unless more-or-less 'everyone' is well aware that the freedom they have been
granted is not unconditional;
-
in 2012 an anthropologist
suggested that, while Australians increasingly put 'no religion' on census
forms, they are perhaps the most spiritual people in the world because they
have invented their own 'deities' to worship (such as the 'digger', the
'Australian farmer', the 'Aussie battler', the 'working class man' and the
'noble Aboriginal') [1]
;
-
in 2013 a social commentator suggested that Australians' values were
changing quickly because of a rapid increase in
‘progressive’ thinking (which tends to be associated with godlessness) led
by major universities and Greens-leaning inner-suburbs [1].
-
Western civilization is adrift in a world of ideas – having been
uncoupled from religion for a century. The Judeo-Christian ethic
tradition that endured (within a secular / modernist rationale) is
under threat. The groupthink of Left orthodoxy is accelerating the
demise of liberal values on which Western culture was built. The Left
is encouraging separation from West’s philosophical / religious past.
But the Right is silent on liberal values. The dilution of Western
values can be seen most clearly in media – which censors public debate
to promote politically correct angle. In 1973 Irving Kristol wrote of
the depletion of moral capital in the West. Society was living off
accumulated moral capital from traditional religion – but once
expended society’s foundations would be uncertain. Post-modernism is
in the final stages of its journey from university campuses to
dominating ‘acceptable’ opinion in wider society. It does not allow
debate about what is right and wrong. Postmodernists originally sought
to do away with notions of rights and wrong – but subsequently decided
to redefine these to suit themselves (ie to blame West for everything
and portray Western values by default as inferior to any other).
Tearing down Western values has become an end in itself. What replaces
it is beside the point [1]
-
Christianity has established the foundations of a society in which
people are concerned for others' welfare - yet those foundations are
being lost
Decline of Christian Church has left a deposit – most people
understand mores of being human. There is an egalitarian
attitude to all human beings – but few would recall Paul’s
statement about this being due to viewing all peoples as one in
Christ. This attitude to all people is central to our culture –
yet it can’t be derived rationally or based on philosophers.
Jesus’ teaching about ‘who is my neighbour’ has been
institutionalised as social services to provide for those in
need. Yet this was based on self-giving life of Jesus.
Relationships based on love and forgiveness are seen as better
than those based on law and duty. But love is seen as valuable
without recognising that the love Jesus demonstrated but
anything but romantic. The idea of laying down one’s life for
one’s friends comes from Jesus. In challenging religion, its
overwhelming good has been forgotten. As the nurturing
foundation fades, how will the ‘building’ erected on it be
maintained? The core of Christianity is worship. If principles
and values are extracted from the tradition without worship,
grace is lost and all that is left is law (which leads to
death). There are already significant departures from inherited
ethos (eg a loss of sense of responsibility for the common
good). Responsibility to neighbours has become selective. The
unborn are not seen to be equal. Individual human rights are
seen as all that is important. Christianity opposed the worship
of idols. Now idols are everywhere (eg trust in science /
technology / markets / intellect / technology). But technology
has its limits. Markets can lead to social inequality. Freedom
seems empty as people are not helped to understand what is good
and lasting. The sexual revolution loosed marriage bonds and
confused the young. There is a need for more than being smart.
But the foundation is missing. Secular humanists can espouse
principles derived from Christianity – but they can’t ensure the
freedom that is inherent in Christianity. And turning principles
into law and political correctness is suffocating [1].
- Attacks against Christianity and
Christians are seen to have have significantly increased in
Australia
Numerous attacks have
reportedly occurred
against Christians and others who have expressed critical views
of same-sex marriage proposals.
Islamist attacks against Christians
in the Middle East are part of unrelenting war. The region is
being Islamised. 1m Jews were driven from Arab / Muslim nations
between 2020 and 1970. Few Jews now live in the region outside
Israel - yet Israel has 20% Muslims. The same applies to
Christians. Many Muslims now live in what were once seen as
Christian nations - and they enjoy freedom of religion. At the
same time Christians have been forced from Muslim lands. 14% of
Middle Eastern populations were Christian in 1910 - down to 4%
in 2010. Christianity in the West is also under (verbal) attack
by those who preach a fundamentalist secular creed, atheism. For
most of the 20th century citizens of the West who were not
religious believes were pragmatic agnostics. They had not
rejected the idea that there might be a God. Agnostics were
tolerant of believers. Atheists has a secular faith believing
that God was created by mankind. Now atheist are more certain of
their cause than most believers. There is a sneering smugness
popularised by Richard Dawkins directed against Christians but
not Muslims. This dismisses the intelligence / judgment of their
predecessors and discredits the basis of Western civilization.
Western leaders (eg Newton, Shakespeare, Bacon) believed that
the Old Testament was the history of the world and that God had
sent his Son to redeem the world. They may have been mistaken -
but they helped build Western society. However believers are now
seen to be incapable of independent thought. Christianity is
being attacked in the Middle East by those who want to kill
Christians and by those in the West who believe that
Christianity is incompatible with rational thought [1]
[ CPDS Comment: widespread Christian adherence
is needed to create a social / political and economic
environment in which rationality can be a reasonably reliable
basis for practical decision making - see
Cultural
Foundations of Western Progress: the Realm of the Rational
Responsible Individual)
And without a strong embedded Christian ethical ideal in many Australians there
is a weakening foundation for 'responsible liberty' or thus for a
system of law and government based on individual liberty.
Escalating social dysfunctions (see
below) provide evidence that it is
increasingly unwise to presume that Australians will have a strong innate
sense of individual responsibility. Conspicuous amongst the resulting dysfunctions are: sexual abuse of
(perhaps) 20% of children (and official
resistance to examining this phenomenon); child neglect; the breakdown of up to 50% of marriages;
the freedom from family and other responsibilities that men gained (at the expense of
women and children) as result of the sexual revolution; the escalation of
single parent families in which children tend to suffer disadvantages;
worsening business ethics; widespread bullying; and increased domestic / random violence.
Indicators of the decay of an ingrained value-others-as-oneself ethical ideal
and of its adverse social consequences include:
- self-centeredness as the defining characteristic of the (so-called)
‘me’ generation (the 'Baby boomers');
- an increasing emphasis on individual rights, rather than on
responsibility for the welfare of others;
- the emergence of a 'punk' culture in the 1960s which seemed to
make individual irresponsibility (eg via drug abuse and indiscriminate
sex) into an underground 'religion' - noting for example the wide
influence attributed to
Lou Reed;
- virtual freedom from family responsibilities which men have had the
potential to enjoy since the sexual revolution of the 1960s and 1970s
- a freedom which now appears to be translating into:
- poor educational
achievements by boys who lack of male role-models [1];
- low fertility rates as women find it increasingly difficult to
find a man willing to commit to parenthood [1;
- a perception that free sex and feminist marriage makes young men
'feckless' (ie unwilling to work hard / take responsibility)' [1]
- the rapid growth of what has been called a Narcissistic
Personality Disorder - characteristically involving parents who place
all emphasis on themselves and none on their children. When both
parents suffer this, massive problems arise in divorces - as litigants
make zero concessions. Emphasis is placed on their rights, not on
their children's rights. Social researchers blame this on
Generation I - and 'its all about me' traits fuelled by social media [1]
- narcissistic (self-love) personality traits are increasing. 25% of
students revealed such traits strongly in 2006 (up from 15% in 1982).
80% of people thought they were important in 1980s compared with 12%
in 1952. An epidemic of poor parenting is seen as the cause [1]
- emphasis on self-fulfillment, sometimes including veneration of self
as a fragment of the divine (which seem to be the core of 'New Age' and
growing (pseudo) Buddhist traditions);
- a perceived inability to make moral judgments [1]
- Morality? What were once seven deadly sins (that led to spiritual
death and damnation) - namely lust, gluttony, avarice, sloth, anger,
envy and pride - have all become behavioural problems requiring treatment,
not punishment, except for pride that has become a virtue (as an antidote
to the sense of low self-esteem that is seen as the source of many social
and psychological problems). And what were once virtues (humility, kindness,
abstinence, chastity, patience, liberality, diligence) are now also
seen as requiring correction through counseling (Furedi F., 'The seven
deadly ills', Australian, 2-3/2/02)
- escalating drug abuse apparently expressing a desire to 'escape' from
a unhappy lives [1];
- weakening of ethics in:
- business [1] - which (a)
erodes public confidence in commercial institutions that are essential
to economic productivity (b) undermines the status that professionals
gained by the ideal of putting community interests before one's own
and (c) and requires significantly more complex and costly accountability
procedures;
- government - associated with increasingly lying [1]
- concerns (by APRA) that something is seriously wrong with
Australia's banks related to a lack of ethical behaviour [1];
- the level of corruption by banks, other corporations and wealthy
people became a matter of political concern in April 2016 [1];
- ASIC told banks in mid 2016 that there was a critical need to
improve staff culture - following a survey which revealed poor staff
ethics [1]
- the breakdown of organized civil society (see
Social capital);
- the emergence of
dysfunctional interpersonal relationships (including:
- persistent (and explicit) refusal by governments to address the
vast majority of child sexual abuse that occurs in family / community
contexts (see Reducing Child Sex
Abuse Mainly Requires Potential Offenders to have a Conscience) ;
- official government acceptance of homosexual behaviour (eg in the
areas of tax, superannuation, Medicare benefits, Centrelink payments,
child support and immigration), though such acceptance seems to
constitute endorsement of past child abuse and neglect, and to
facilitate future sexual abuse of children (see
Breaking Off the Long Engagement?);
- deterioration in community health associated with increased obesity,
because children's outdoor activities are constrained by fear of strangers
[1]
- Both Prime Minister and leader of the Opposition have expressed concern
about the social consequences of changes in Australian values and culture
[1]
Part of the social breakdown mentioned above (eg child abuse) is overly
associated with disadvantaged communities (eg those suffering high unemployment,
low education etc) [1].
However:
- the existence of a correlation between social breakdown and disadvantage
does not show what has caused the correlation - though a key requirement
for overcoming disadvantage for individuals is probably that they gain
stronger support from responsible family and community members (see
Commentary
on Is the Smart State a Just State?).
- some indicators of social breakdown (eg in family relationships) are
more widespread than serious social disadvantage;
- changes in attitudes which are likely to contribute have occurred,
and the apparent scale of the social breakdown does not support the view
that disadvantage is the major cause;
Part of the social stresses identified are also undoubtedly associated
with pressure for harder work [3]
- while it has also been suggested that the major cause lies in the failure
of men to take on a larger share of household tasks as women have gained
equality, and increasingly participate in the workforce [1]
Others have attempted to explain changes in the nature of relationships
and the growth of 'rampant individualism' in terms of various consequences
of globalization [1].
Others again have suggested that the worst of the problems are over
and the situation is improving as a result of general economic
prosperity [1]
Restraining Freedom As 'Responsible Liberty'
Fades
Unless a 'put-others-first' ethical ideal is widely re-established through religion
which is separate from the state / community pressure, new approaches to
social control will continue to be seen to be needed to ensure compliance
with elite perceptions of appropriate behavior.
Indicators of the growth of, and pressure for, authoritarian 'social / ethical' regulation
include:
- the perceived need for the state to:
- restrain domestic violence [1]
and violence in schools [1,
2]. A major government program to prevent / respond to domestic
violence was launched in late 2015 - without apparent recognition
that this is only one of many types of violence that arguably
require a non-state solution (see
Piecemeal Response Show
Australia Still Doesn't 'Get' Moral Breakdown);
-
prevent parents from smacking their children [1];
- teach school children to be nice to each other [1];
- implement remedial strategies to prevent bullying in schools and homes [1],
and at work [1,
2];
- enact laws to ensure etiquette in people's behaviour on footpaths
[1];
- remove disruptive families from their neighbourhood [1];
- force men to take more responsibility for household
duties [1];
- take a hands-on role in promoting and sustaining
marriage [1]
- give Aboriginal elders legislative powers to order addicted
persons into rehabilitation, mediate between groups and hold parents
responsible for juvenile offenders [1]
-
defining a set of moral standards
for politicians by setting down a code of conduct [1];
-
the reported loss of public interest in substantive policy issues - with
concern only for personal impacts and whether politicians reflect their values [1];
- a stream of initiatives by government in the UK aimed at improving
people's behaviour [1];
- legal action against institutions for the sexual misdeeds of their
staff [1]
- which creates a requirement for managements to try to control interpersonal
relationships;
- checks on teachers in relation to child abuse - a practice which was
seen as likely to be inadequate [1];
- proposals by ASCA for preventing child sex abuse (a phenomenon
that was acknowledged to be widespread) which amount to promoting
community morality. However it seemed to be expected that morality of
individual behaviour would be promoted by government policies and
programs, rather than independently of the state [1]
- the suggested creation of special courts or other arrangements to
deal with sexual abuse of children [1,
2] - which apparently mainly occurs when children
live with adults who are not their biological parents;
- arguments by both Australian state and commonwealth governments that the other
needs to take responsibility for dealing with the massive problem of child
sex abuse [1];
- the introduction of shared responsibility agreements designed to influence
the actions of aboriginal parents [1]
- federal government proposals to restrict the way in which welfare
payments can be used by some households (eg those crippled by
alcoholism or unable to manage their children) [1]
- the introduction of legislation to protect the disabled from abusive
carers [1];
- ALP proposals for government machinery for micro-supervision of
the fairness of employee-employer relationships (see
Fair Work
Australia: Establishing the Machinery of a Socialist State);
- a perceived need for a Statement of National Values (focused on: democracy;
equality of all people; religious tolerance; rule of law; mate-ship) [1]
- the blurring of the line between individual and state responsibilities,
and the predicted future increase in the use of formal agreements about
behaviour that could be required in various circumstances (eg as has been
done with indigenous communities) [1]
-
potential and actual breakdown of the separation between state and
religion (ie of the notion of a 'secular' state), eg as indicated by:
Examples of breaking the separation of religion and state
- political activism by church-based organizations [1];
- attempts by the (so called) Secular Party of Australia to make
religion a political issue (see
Challenges Facing the
Secular Party);
- calls for a Prime Minister (an Atheist) to express a 'godless
vision of morality' [1];
- a perceived need to insert 'values' into public debates [1],
and for the Deputy prime Minister to himself stress moral values [1].
And the ALP was said to believe that politics in future would be concerned
solely with values - without concern for traditional political debates
about programs and budgets [1];
- Comment: Determining 'values' through political authorities
would break the separation of church and state
- the perceived intent of an ALP leader to build an election
campaign on religious values [1];
- calls for the adoption of Islamic Sharia Law in
Australia, because of the social and environmental failure of
Christianity and democratic capitalism Advantages were seen to
lie in: (a) Islam being a total system for life which applies to both
personal and governmental affairs; (b) Islam's similarity to the
traditions of indigenous Australians; (c) the loss of values in
Australian life; (d) prohibition under Islam of vices / interest /
homosexuality / exploitation for money / immorality / wife beating /
over-indulgence / rape / paedophilia; and (e) Islam's promotion of
water conservation; and ethics in the workplace. [1]
[Comment: see Sharia 4
Australia?].
- a perceived need for state funding of chaplains in schools [1];
- a political debate about the values
taught in state schools, and in particular:
- the adequacy of the values taught in state schools was questioned
by a Prime Minister and others [1],
and provisions have been made for federal funding to be cut to university
courses which the government objects to [1];
- a study was commissioned by the
Federal education minister on the values which should be inculcated
through the education system [1];
- it was suggested that state schools do not need religion to impart
values like 'inclusiveness, respect for others, ethnic diversity and
multiculturalism', and that religious education should be removed from
the curriculum to make room for other subjects [1]
- Comment on 'Clayton-ism': that writer's preferred alternative was not to
regard any values as better than any others and treat all cultures
equally - which would, in effect, constitute the core of a new official
religion (which could perhaps be called 'Clayton-ism' - the religion
you have when you are not having a religion). Superficially values
included under Clayton-ism would be radically different to Australia's
institutional traditions (and disruptive) because (a) many cultures
that Clayton-ism would include
do not endorse equality
of individuals, (b) some regard
racism as natural
and (c) some are overtly intolerant of religious differences.
However if it was then decided (on some arbitrary basis) that such
features should be excluded, then Clayton-ism would be well on the
way to becoming a prescriptive official state religion
- the federal government's efforts to promote values education can
be seen as attempt by it to be regarded as having moral authority [1]
- the Victorian Government's:
- emphasis on
Respectful Relationships Education as a key means
for combatting domestic violence [CPDS Comment:
This was an extremely strange proposal because: (a) a
lack of appropriate concern for others has become the
source of a huge number of social dysfunctions - not
just domestic violence (see
above); and (b) a lack of
'respect' is only one (and apparently not the most
significant) factor in domestic violence (see
Domestic
Violence);
- apparent determination to promote a state religion
by presenting itself as the authority in relation to the
ethical education of students [1].
Special religious education was removed from class
times. New content on world histories, cultures, faith
and ethics would take its place. Classes on domestic
violence and respectful relationships would be
compulsory for all students. [CPDS Comment:
This seemed a regressive step as special
religious education promotes respect for others (ie love
for others as oneself) without
reliance on the human / government claims of moral authority
that Victoria is introducing and which must further undermine
the foundations of Australia's liberal legal and
government institutions]
- officially-sponsored
proposals ("Religion,
Cultural Diversity and Safeguarding Australia", 2004) to promote
religious harmony in Australia through a government-driven process to:
(a) shift both public institutions and the community generally towards
officially being a 'multi-faith' (rather than a Christian) society;
and (b) promote particular 'civil' values.
- Comment: This proposal seemed to
constitute a version of the 'Clayton-ism' mentioned
above and to emerge without consideration of: (a) the likely
dependence of Australia's liberal legal and governance systems on
having a community with 'Judeo-Christian' expectations about moral behaviour
being controlled primarily by individual consciences responsible to
God, rather than by social pressures which generally seems to be the
alternative; and (c) the damage that would result from state efforts to
control the community's religious practices or 'values' - given the
importance for individual liberty of separating church and state, and
the social, economic and political advantages of that liberty;
- proposals by the Greens to eliminate any right
of religious freedom in relation to its proposed
laws related to same-sex marriage [1]
- a review of materials used for religious
instruction in schools by the Queensland Government
and an academic's call for government authorities to
vet material used for religious education in schools
[1]
- attempts by self-appointed (moral) 'authorities' to enforce community acceptance of (what opponents
describe as merely) 'politically
correct' ideas, behaviours and attitudes by personal attacks on
skeptical individuals. Communal pressure to ensure individual
conformity with 'politically correct' ideas is likely to constrain
individual difference / initiative / innovation (and thus
progressive social, economic and political change) in much the
same way that radical Islamic approaches to the communal / state
enforcement of compliance with religious-legalists' interpretation
of what Islam requires has
constrained the
prospects of Muslim-dominated societies. See also
The Church of Political Correctness Threatens
National Progress;
Political correctness has become a form of intimidation
that is damaging both individuals and society. It tends to be
irrational and lack common sense and to ignore truth - because a
protected groups is not to be challenged. It can be likened to the
tale of the emperor's new clothes. [Examples were suggested] [1].
People accuse others of doing things that are wrong or 'politically incorrect -
while others resent the implications that those who do so are seeing themselves
as superior. John Stuart Mill criticized both state constraints on freedom - and
the tyranny of prevailing opinion where the community imposes its ideas /
practices on those who dissent by non-regulatory means). What goes on in the name
of 'political correctness' is an example of the latter. This is inconsistent
with a free society and unpopular with many people. One problem is that
different things upset different people - so the issue is subjective. [1]
Children will now have been exposed to political
correctness since they started school. This started with
totalitarian threats (eg by Stalin) to kill those who
did not follow the party line. It is not enforced to
protect the marginalized - but the conceit / power of
enforcers. What is enforced can be ridiculous - but
needs to be accepted when backed by force. It is not
safe to just accept the script - because what is being
enforced can change. [1]
One observer
suggested
that political correctness can give rise to political
extremism - because it stifles ordinary discussion and
leads those with different opinions towards extremism in
frustration. Given the parallel between political
correctness and radical Islam that was noted
above, it may be that
the need to over-ride the Islamic equivalent of
'politically correct' movements explains the prevalence
of authoritarian regimes in Muslim majority states.
The former head of UK Equalities and Human Rights
Commission who popularized the term 'Islamophobia' to
denigrate those who pointed to difficulties in
integrating Muslims now reportedly argues that those who
contended that no such obstacles existed have been the
main problem (see
here)
The politically correct class (PCC) in Australia is
like an evangelical religious movement - and this has
perhaps arisen as traditional Protestant church groups
have seen memberships decline. Some people want to be in
groups with coherent beliefs which they want to spread
to others. While their opinions may be valid, the PCC is
distinguished by not wanting to debate them. Anyone who
disagrees is seen to be evil and to deserve suppression.
The PCC is small in number but influential because it
dominates large sections of the media, universities,
legal professions, bureaucracies and some large
corporations. Anyone in those bodies who expresses
different opinions will have limited career prospects.
The PCC came to capture these organisations from the
early 1980s perhaps because of huge expansion of
universities and introduction of PCC material into
schools at that time. Australia is worse than UK
and US in stifling public debate on social and political
questions. This is difficult to correct because juniors
soon realize what they are expected to believe - so the
system is self perpetuating. There are still contrary
voices - but they need to have established positions to
be immune from persecution [1]
A former devout Muslim
argues
that, though Islam contains good features, it can never
be a religion of peace because it also endorses the use
of extreme violence to achieve them. Political
correctness has been the major obstacle to recognising
the resulting threats.
A weekend conference Christian groups planned
at a hotel to discuss a forthcoming plebesite in
relation to whether or not same sex marriage should be
accepted had to be abandoned after threats by same-sex
marriage supporters caused the hotel management to fear
for the safety of staff and guests [1]
- the perception that the 'Australian of the Year' process had
been captured by 'social engineers' with a particular agenda who
appointed individuals who then lectured the community on their
perceived flaws [1];
- concerns that freedom of religion and speech are being eroded by
anti-discrimination laws [1];
- suggestions that freedom of religion is at risk (from
political Islam, humanism and 'civic religion') and that
particular emphasis is directed against Christianity [1].
If valid, the latter would be significant as: (a) religious
freedom arguably had its origin in New Testament Christianity;
and (b) the emphasis on this from the time of the Reformation
was the source of liberal institutions in Western societies more
generally (see
Where Did Religious Freedom Come From?)
-
proposals for legalization of gay marriage, which some see as providing a wedge for the
state to interfere in traditionally-private family life (see
Broader issues related to gay marriage);
- a perceived 'tyranny' associated pressure not to 'offend' sexual
minorities. Victimhood is now a major focus in Australia's
universities. There is no appeal against the ad-hoc judicial system
that enforces 'political correctness' - yet transgression can
destroy lives [1]
- political activism by the judiciary. For
example:
- A majority decision by the US Supreme Court to make same-sex
marriage legal in the US on the basis of the equality provisions
in the US constitution was seen by dissenting opinions to: (a)
not actually based on the constitution as the latter had said
nothing about same-sex marriage; and (b) to have the effect, not
of shielding minorities, but of crushing dissent [1];
- an emphasis on people's 'rights' to particular benefits rather
than on individuals' responsibility to consider the welfare of
others;
- the apparent emergence of dogmatism in some areas of science.
It has been suggested, for example, that science has become a sort of
church, with scientists being virtual priests. Like the church in
earlier centuries, scientists feel responsible for the intellectual
orderliness of society (see Bauer H.
Dogmatism in Science and Medicine, 2012);
- the emergence of autocratic claims to the moral high ground on the
basis of fairly narrow understandings of the issues. This included:
- 'antidiscrimination' legislation which suppresses the free expression
of some ideas [1]
or protects some behavioural choices that are traditionally seen as immoral,
and lead to (sometimes quite unforeseen) social dysfunctions [1];
- the expressed concern that churches do not recognize professionally
derived ethics, but have treated them as part of universal moral principles
[1]. [An aside:
The significance of 'professionally' derived ethics from the viewpoint
of the churches (ie of eating the fruit of the tree of knowledge of good
and evil) is presumably embodied in Genesis 2-3];
- research by the Australian Computer Society into ethical standards
that should be adopted in that industry [1];
- advocacy of a Bill of Rights [1]
as a means to establish moral rights [1]
or national values [1],
or because it can no longer be assumed that elected representatives will
act in the general community interest [1].
Victoria is to follow ACT in establishing a statutory charter of rights
and responsibilities [1]
- Comment: advocacy of a Bill / Charter of Rights
seems seems to be justified by the view that individual rights have
been constrained in some respect. However, it is frequently pointed
out that in practice a Bill of Rights
would seem likely to compound such constraints by limiting rights in future to those which are prescribed.
Traditionally, under common law, individuals have been able to do what
is not prohibited, but a Bill of Rights would seem to reverse this
presumption of freedom and guarantee only the right to do what is
specifically permitted. When an issue arises in future that no one
has previously considered, it would reasonably be argued that the
right did not exist because it was not mentioned in the Bill of
Rights
- the establishment of Family Law, the Family Court and the Child Support
Agency to enforce child support. In some respects the latter has
raised the cost of 'free' love to a very high level.
- Family law, it may also be noted, has been seen as a source of many
problems [1],
and (in Queensland at least) the
Families
Department seems to experience considerable difficulties. Moreover
the cost of child support (combined with the high incidence of family
breakdown) seems likely to act as a real disincentive to marriage and
parenthood - at an inconvenient time for an aging population;
- the creation in Queensland of machinery to 'keep government honest'
in the era following the 1980s' Fitzgerald inquiry which:
- was described by one expert observer as creating the most complex
system of government in the Western world [1];
and
- was seen 15 years later to require scaling back because the resulting
'red tape' made government ineffective [1]
There has also been:
- a suggestion that a breakdown in civil society due to loss of
trust is interfering with the effectiveness of economic transactions,
and that this might need to be resolved by the churches [1].
- recognition by Christian leaders of the effects on Australia's values
and institutions if its religious foundations are shifted [1].
A similar argument was developed in
The Re-emergence of 'gods'
(2015)
Consequences?
The effect of a perceived need to apply external constraints to most aspects
of individual behaviour would be to eliminate the liberty that has been central
to past legal and political systems and to the economic success that has been
enjoyed. Moreover externally driven morality (by moral legalism or social sanctions)
does not seem very effective.
A Chinese writer (whose work the author can no longer locate) commented
on the difference between doing the right thing when others were watching
- or all of the time when conscience was the guide. Islamic legalism seems
to require threats of horrendous punishment.
New testament writers commented on the fact that 'no one could ever live
under the Mosaic law'. In earlier eras, blood sacrifice was one 'solution'
that was found to the failure of moral legalism to prevent what leaders
saw as rampant sin in a nation. Knowing how widely the moral law was abused,
but powerless to do anything about it, community leaders could show how
seriously they viewed the problem by arranging to sacrifice an innocent
scapegoat. An interesting parallel may be drawn with the official blind
eye that was turned to the problem of child sexual abuse in Australian families
and the political 'assassination' of the G-G in 2003.
The erosion of the moral foundations of individual liberty is also a threat
to national security because of the risks associated with possible terrorist
attacks by Islamist extremists. This arises because making a convincing case
for civil liberties in Muslim dominated countries is (probably) the key to defeating
the ideology of the spiritual leaders who motivate militants to commit acts
of terror - yet the social symptoms which have resulted from the loss of the
ethical basis for moral interpersonal relations is a major obstacle to the credibility
of any such case (see
Combating
Terrorism with Civil Liberties)
In early 2014 an Australian senator expressed concern about dysfunctional
family arrangements - and was criticised by others for raising such
concerns. The senator had not however mentioned the potential adverse
political and economic consequences of those social dysfunctions (see
Family Issues).
See remedies suggested in A Nation
Building Agenda below
|
The Need for Nation Building
|
Recognising a Need for Nation Building
Starting to Acknowledge Ineffectual Government?
In July 2010, various observers finally started to acknowledge that a federal Government's behaviour
implied the existence of systemic problems in Australia's machinery of
government.
Even at the time of its election, the Rudd Government showed signs of likely incompetence (see
Populism Trumps Electoral Victory) and there were many examples of futile or
counterproductive actions in addition to
those which finally achieved public recognition in mid 2010 (see Reconsidering
the Origins of Kevin Rudd's Failure).
Kevin
Rudd's subversion of federal cabinet was not just the work of a rogue
individual. The ease with which this was done for 2 years exposes a
dangerous flaw in Australia's system of governance that has merely been
papered over by eliminating Rudd. Bypassing cabinet resulted in serious
consequences - ie the dreadful RSPT, which caused significant damage to the
country. It should not be assumed that this could not happen again (eg
suppose a terrorist incident had allowed Rudd to reinforce his autocratic
style). Or what if he had been a more competent / malevolent demagogue able
to manipulate public opinion and remain popular. Most government decisions
over the past two years were made by the 'gang of four' not by cabinet.
Companies now have to publish corporate governance statements - but these
don't exist for government. Canberra elites are telling themselves that the
flaws in the system do not need to be addressed, because Rudd was brought
down. But there is a need for a constitutional change that recognises the
authority / responsibility of ministers, or perhaps a 'Statement of
Governance Practice'. The policy mistakes of the past six months should
never be allowed to happen again. (Kohler A
Ending Australian Autocracy,
BusinessSpectator, 2/7/10
A somewhat related view was expressed by
Peter Botsman in
Empty Rightousness – the Real Problem of Modern
Labor (July 2010).
For most of 2010 the Rudd Government had been a flying logjam - with
ministers and public servants chasing the PM and his kitchen cabinet around
the country hoping for decisions on the policy dilemmas that were piling up.
Instead of decisions there were constant requests for more information /
analyses / options. Advirors were not relied upon to present the best
available options. The government won the daily new cycle, but lost the
battle in terms of the need for a clear strategic direction. [1]
International efforts to reduce GHG
emissions have been very costly and produced no benefits. Claims that reductions
can be achieved at minimal costs were based on insane assumptions about the
value of yet undeveloped technologies. Such claims were part of a general patter
whereby Western leaders were not willing to tell the electorate the truth about
the high cost of shifting to a low-carbon economy . The grotesque misuse of the
Treasury, the politicisation of its advice, and its entry into direct political
combat, with Ken Henry acting like an unelected cabinet minister proposing
policy and defending it in parliament and in the community, is one of the very
worst and most institutionally damaging results of the Rudd interregnum. [1]
The most serious of these for the future arguably
involved 'reforming' Australia's health and hospital system by
increasing centralised control (see
Making
a Bad Situation Worse?). That 'reform' seemed to assume that service
delivery could be centrally managed by defining 'efficient prices' for health
services - though (as shown by Soviet economic failures) central
authorities can not define prices that will lead to the production of goods
and services that meet real needs.
Eventually the Rudd Government showed such extreme dysfunctions that it was
impossible to continue turning a blind eye, and Mr Rudd was
replaced as Prime Minister by his deputy on the grounds that 'the government
had lost its way' [1].
However concern about systemic defects soon subsided, even though:
There seemed to be no serious effort to understand the causes of these problems.
Business leaders, for example, expressed concern about the policy and
practical paralysis that affected governments, but seemed oblivious to the
need to address the source of these problems.
Overcoming Australia's Government Paralysis (email sent 12/12/10)
John Durie,
The Australian,
Re: ‘CEOs
decry policy vacuum’, The Australian, 11-12/12/10
Your article
recorded the concerns of various business leaders about a lack of progress in
addressing important policy issues. However there is a need to look beyond those
particular issues at the causes of political and institutional paralysis. Until
structural obstacles also receive attention, little progress is likely.
My
interpretation of your article:
Australia’s business leaders are concerned by policy inaction, Carbon pricing,
tax and infrastructure are key issues. But bold decisions are being hampered by
a hung parliament. Terry Davis (Coco-Cola Amatil) sees a policy vacuum
resulting. Bernie Brooks (Myer) is concerned with protracted decision making /
waste. Graham Twartz (Hills Holdings) sees the need for decisive / accountable
government. None saw the NBN as a major issue, through Telstra (David Thodey)
and Hills saw it as an opportunity.Leaders (eg James Fazzino, Incitec Pivot)
were concerned with hard infrastructure to take advantage of industrialisation /
urbanisation in Asia. IAG (Mike Wilkins) was concerned with complacency about
current economic strength, and the unfinished tax reform agenda. Leaders saw a
need for business tax cuts, and were concerned about skills shortages. Richard
Goyder (Wesfarmers) saw the need for increased labour mobility. A need for early
decisions about responding to climate change and energy efficiency was perceived
by David Thody, Grant King (Origin Energy), Mark Selway (Boral), Alan Joyce
(Qantas) and Marius Kloppers (BHP). Resolution of issues related to mining taxes
was perceived to be critical by Tom Albanese (Rio Tinto) and Andrew Forrest
(Fortescue), and a taskforce led by Don Argus will report to government on this
soon.
At present
business leaders seem to have unrealistically simplistic views of what is
required to achieve the outcomes they seek (see comments on ‘Seeking Magic
Solutions’ below). Policy and practical paralysis must continue, unless and
until community leaders:
- start to consider not only desired policy outcomes but also the obstacles to
good government that have emerged naturally or from unwise advice; and
- put
in place the supporting machinery now required for Australia’s system of
government to again become effective.
Some suggestions
about institutional reforms that might be required are in
A Nation Building Agenda. This refers to addressing challenges such as:
- Weak policy development capacity due to the lucky-country’s traditional
dependence on natural resources, and copying others’ policy initiatives;
- The
increasing complexity (eg interconnection) of issues, which facilitates
electoral support for ‘populist’ (ie simplistic but unrealistic) policy;
- Dependence on political leadership in addressing system-wide social and economic
challenges, thus often increasing controls rather than opportunities;
- The
adverse effect of centralised control and revenues on the grass-roots initiative
and responsibility needed to deal effectively with many challenges;
- The
lack of real Asia-literacy (ie ability to understand that increasingly
significant region from an ‘East Asian’ viewpoint); and
- Politicisation of government machinery (often inadvertently), thereby further
depriving elected governments of practical and realistic support.
The speculations
in that document may be of interest, though they are are at best a starting
point.
John Craig
Seeking Magic
Solutions
Some formal
submissions by business leaders have been unrealistically simplistic. For
example, the Business Council of Australia (in Bradley G.,
Parliament must focus on reform where there is broad agreement,
BCA, 16/9/10) suggested a policy agenda for the federal government that would
not only focus on issues about which there was already broad agreement (such as
parliamentary reform and improving indigenous Australians’ life opportunities)
but also provide leadership in: (a) formulating a national infrastructure plan
(involving both regulatory / pricing policies and priority projects to boost
national productivity); (b) tax reforms; (c) national energy security; (d)
focusing COAG on fewer more-important issues; and (e) promoting integrity in
federal budgets.
The BCA’s
proposals seem unrealistic because they demand outcomes of shambolic machinery
of government.
For example, the
key to effective development of infrastructure arguably lies in overcoming
artificial institutional obstacles to effective action by (mainly) state
governments. The main problems are arguably: (a) fiscal imbalances within
Australia’s federal system; (b) politicisation / deskilling of government
machinery because of a desire to ensure unquestioning compliance; and (c)
attempts to develop functions subject to market failures through market
processes, or to apply business-like methods in undertaking non-business-like
government functions (eg see
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy, 2005).
The BCA’s ‘solution’ involves central planning (eg devising a list of projects
suitable for federal government or private funding) and this would simply
compound problems created in Australia’s system of government generally over the
last few decades. Likewise:
- tax
reform which does not give specific attention to the capacity of state and local
governments to independently fund their primary functions and bear financial
consequences from the success or failure of their effectiveness (or otherwise)
in enabling the development of productive modern economies is inadequate (see
Australia's Future Tax System: The Cost of the Financial Crisis and the
Opportunity to Fix Government). There is however no serious attention to
the effect on the operational effectiveness of governments in major proposals
for tax reform (such as the Henry Review);
- the
problems in Australia’s overly-complex machinery of government can’t be resolved
by limiting the Commonwealth to micro-managing a smaller number of state
functions through COAG. There is rather a need for fundamental reform of the
federal system, to end the suppression of grass roots competencies and
initiative (eg see
Fixing Australia's Federation as well as specific examples of
counter-productive outcomes from attempts to develop idealistic ‘national’
solutions
Making a Bad Situation Worse and
Proposed National History Curriculum: Information without Understanding?);
- there is no point in simply promoting integrity in federal budgets when there
are serious problems in the integrity of state budgets (eg see
CPDS Comments on Queensland’s 2009-10 Budget). Money wasted by state
governments due to the lack of independent policy capacity and internal
competence is just as serious as wastage by the federal government.
Also, your
article recorded calls by many business leaders for firm policy decisions in
relation to climate change, so as to facilitate investment. However until there
is a serious effort to reduce uncertainties in the associated science, it is
simply not realistic to ask for a policy position to be defined that will not be
susceptible to unpredictable change in a few years time (see
Carbon Certainty is a Long Way Off).
S-L-O-W Learners (email sent 16/12/10)
Paul Kelly
The Australian
Re:
‘No time to rest on our laurels’, The Australian, 15/12/10
Your article,
which I have outlined below, drew attention to frustrations which ‘outsiders’
(eg business leaders and economic policy experts) have about the complacency
that ‘political-media insiders’ now exhibit in relation to Australia’s economic
prospects.
However, those
‘outsiders’ are themselves partly to blame. Some past ‘reform’ initiatives they
advocated have contributed to making Australian governments ineffectual, because
those who led in developing and selling radical changes that were hoped to boost
economic efficiency had little experience or knowledge of the nature and
functions of government. The fact that the risk of making governments
ineffectual still seems to elude those who advocate continuation of Australia’s
past approach to economic reform implies that they are S-L-O-W learners.
My reasons for
suggesting this are outlined below, together with observations about:
- Apparent defects in the theoretical foundations of conventional ideas about
improving Australia’s economic prospects; and
- Whether ‘Asian values’ might be more relevant to Australia’s future, as your
article implied, than those embodied in (say) European-style social democracy.
Regards
John Craig
Outline of
Article and Detailed Comments
My
interpretation of your article:
Australia is at risk because of complacency. Political-media ‘insiders’ are more
complacent than ‘outsiders’. Insiders see the 2010 political compromise as
workable with economic success assured. Business executives are very frustrated.
Kim Williams (Foxtel) sees ‘blanding out’ that can only lead to failure.
Monday’s AFR reported on BCA forum’s doubts about ALP’s ability to set strong
policy agenda – with concerns related to: minority government; NBN; skill
shortages; infrastructure; red tape; and lack of federal-state collaboration.
Gary Banks (Productivity Commission) warned that rising national income from
resources boom was concealing poor productivity performance. Government must
both deliver fiscal restraint and manage structural pressures associated with
mining boom. Banks argues there is a need for: labour mobility; less industry
assistance; reform of defence procurement; and less anti-competitive regulation
and regulation that adds to business costs. Also industrial relations reform is
needed, as well as carbon pricing rather than more expensive alternatives. Ross
Garnaut continues to warn about complacency. Judith Sloan (for CIS) warns that
Fair Work Act poses distinct economic risks. An OECD report shows problems in
students’ attainment in maths and sciences. The ALP seems confused and divided
over such issues. In the past OECD praised ‘Australian model’ of pro-market
reform based on: leadership; identifying and selling reforms that promote both
productivity and equity. But this model has faded. Treasurer argues that
Australia is well placed to benefit from Asian economic power. But Australia’s
values are more at home with declining Europe. Asian values are: personal
improvement; economic competition; educational excellence; national pride;
strong family ties; cultural traditionalism and rising religious faith. Are
these Australia’s values? Many seem opposed to social-democratic and green
progressivism that shape ALP. GFC has delivered a shattering intellectual and
moral message to the world. US is wounded but European model is crippled.
Europe’s system of government debt, entrenched welfare, extensive regulation and
tolerance of all as unifying values is broken. ALP needs to put steel into its
economic thinking. The requirements for success have never been more obvious,
yet they are not mentioned by insiders to Canberra’s political-media culture.
There is no doubt
about the need to end complacency.
However
complacency about the causes of governmental paralysis is as damaging as
complacency about new productivity-enhancing initiatives (see
Overcoming Australia’s Government Paralysis). The latter
suggests that some past productivity-oriented reforms have contributed to
seriously eroding the effectiveness of governments – though they were, by no
means, the only factor.
Dysfunctional
government has become the norm in Australia’s recent history. The lack of
substance in the Rudd Government’s policy agenda should have been obvious in
2007 (see
Populism Trumps Electoral Victory), rather than in mid 2010. Other
Australian governments had been publicly perceived to be ineffectual for years
(see
Failure was not Confined to the Rudd Government).
One reason was
that, starting in the 1980s, all Australian governments had progressively been
through a similar process of managerialist / new-public-management ‘reform’ (see
Decay of Australian Public Administration, 2002). Radical reforms intended
to promote
efficiency and effectiveness, often proved dysfunctional in practice because:
- those advising about ‘reform’ (often with business or economic backgrounds)
tended to lack realistic understanding of the nature and functions of
government. Success with governments’ core roles (ie creating a legal framework
for social and economic transactions in the community; and providing goods and
services that are complicated by serious market failures) depends ultimately on
experience and knowledge (see
Governing is not just Running a Large Business, 2002). However
efficiency-oriented ‘reformers’, who often advocated business-like practices,
were unaware of this. In particular microeconomic ‘reforms’ undertaken under
National Competition Policy sometimes had the unintended effect of eroding the
abilities required for effective government (see
Neglected Side Effects, 2004); and.
- politicians took advantage of the ‘managerialist’ assumption that management was
a generalist activity (which implied that managers did not need to know much
about the functions they were ‘managing’). As experience and knowledge were
derided, governments agencies tended to be stacked with cronies and ‘yes men’.
[Note added later: Ignoring the existing body of
experience and knowledge to achieve a particular reform agenda is hazardous,
because governments' established institutions will embody the results of (say)
1000 prior reform agendas, most of which those concerned with the (say) 10
latest trendy issues will be unaware of. And once everything has been 'torn down
to start again' so that their 10 goals are facilitated, failures must escalate
because of the necessarily-limited knowledge of the latest batch of reformers].
Damage was done
because of the lack of understanding or consideration of the requirements for
effective government (or concern with the side effects of ‘reform’) by those who
advocated radical changes to promote efficiency. A parallel with recent
observations about the source of problems in Europe is apt.
There is a fundamental flaw in the European project. Europe’s economic crisis
resulted in part from reckless spending. Also common interest rates were set
that were too low in some countries and too high in others, while the Euro
blocked devaluation as a relief valve for struggling economies. However these
are bye- products of constructivist roots of the European project. EU is example
of constructivist hubris Hayek described. He defined this as the belief that all
social and cultural institutions were not only created by man but could be
easily changed according to man’s wishes and beliefs. This follows from the
rationalist view of society (of Descartes and Voltaire) and contrasts with the
British empiricist tradition (of Locke, Hume and Smith). Constructivists believe
that anything in society can be altered / improved, while empiricists believe
that such attempts can be dangerous. Later Hayek turned the empiricist tradition
into his theory about social and economic structures depending on dispersed
knowledge which is too complex to be centralised in any one mind. This is why
disregarding grown institutions is bound to fail. EU was a project imposed
top-down on people of Europe. It was driven by intellectuals and politicians on
the basis of their conclusions about what was needed for peace and prosperity.
The EU did not start as a popular movement, but as a political / academic ideal.
‘Europe’ remains an artificial construct. Europe’s crisis shows what happens
when economic and social structures are wilfully ignored and replaced by systems
designed in academic ivory towers and the backrooms of power. Putting design
over experience and planning over evolution contains the seeds of disaster (Hartwich
O. ‘A
fundamental Euro flaw’, Business Spectator, 16/12/10)
Furthermore
Australia’s ‘ideal’ pro-market reform process involved advocacy of conventional
economic theories that seem no longer adequate.
Reasons for this
are speculated in
The Advantages and Limitations of Financial Criteria (2010). For example:
- Economic theory emphasises the role of financial systems in economic
coordination. However the GFC showed that they can also be a source of
instability. Money ordinarily plays a virtuous role (as a store of value and
means of exchange) in simplifying individuals’ economic environment and thus
facilitating rational decision making. However its role can turn ‘vicious’ if
money ceases to be simply a means of measuring economic activities and becomes
rather the primary focus of economic activity. Complex financial systems can
reduce individuals’ ability to make rational decisions;
- It
is no longer appropriate to treat fiscal and monetary policy as the main tools
for economic management, because: (a) neither fiscal nor monetary policy is
adequate for macroeconomic management; and (b) strategic information management
can potentially have valuable economic impacts.
Finally your
question about whether Asian ‘values’ are better than the values underpinning
Europe’s social democracy is more complex than your article suggested.
Firstly ‘Asia’
(if this is taken to refer to societies with an ancient Chinese cultural
heritage) tends not to have values in the way this would be understood in Europe
(ie ideas / ideals people believe in). Rather ‘Asia’ tends to have traditions
(ie things people do). Such societies lack the West’s classical Greek heritage,
that gave rise to an emphasis on abstract ideas, universal values and the notion
of a rule of law (see
East Asia in Competing Civilizations, 2001). Thus government under
‘Asian’ traditions is by man (social elites) rather than by law, and ‘laws’ can
be selectively enforced to discipline those who don’t comply with the
[supposedly] whole-of-society consensus that elites have facilitated (rather than enforced on
the basis of respect for abstract values such as ‘justice’ for individuals).
‘East Asian’ traditions create obligations between individuals with particular
relationships. Universal values (ie those which apply in relationships with ALL
people) are not the norm.
Secondly, there
is no doubt that ‘Europe’ is currently suffering crippling economic stresses and
that some models of social democracy are part of the problem (eg by creating
unsustainable debts because of demands for redistribution of resources that are
not available). However, it can also be noted that:
- broadly based democracy emerged (initially in the UK) at the time of the
industrial revolution partly as a means for redistributing the wealth generated
by mobilizing capital (which had facilitated mechanisation and later mass
production) in industrial economies;
- low-wage competition from emerging economies in capital intensive
‘industrial-era’ functions has been a widely-recognised challenge to previously
advanced economies since the 1960s;
- market liberalization was seen in the 1980s as enabling advanced economies to
sustain high levels of economic productivity in the face of that competition.
However this was inadequate – because competitive pressure alone does not ensure
that the systemic requirements for successful competition exist (see
The Inadequacy of Market Liberalization, 2004). Moreover democratic
governments are structurally incapable (because of the pressures they respond
to) of providing effective leadership in overcoming those constraints (see
Economic Solutions Appear to be Beyond Politics, 1995)
- there are none-less: (a) considerable advantages in democratic political systems
(see
Effective Democracy in Competing Civilizations, 2001); and (b) means
to promote their economic viability (see
A Case for Innovative Economic Leadership, 2009);
- though the GFC has had particularly severe effects in the US and Europe, the
non-capitalistic characteristics of ‘Asian’ models of socio-political-economy
have been a factor in the emergence of the GFC (see
GFC Causes). Moreover those models contain vulnerabilities (see
Heading for a Crash?) and might prove unsustainable in the global economic
environment that emerges when / if the GFC ends (see
Are East Asian Economic Models Sustainable?).
The Secret of Failure: Claim Wisdom Without Practical
Realism
Unfortunately many elected officials in Australia had increasingly acted as if
they had
super-human wisdom and failed to recognise the importance of informed,
practical and independent advice and initiative (see
Intellectual Arrogance: Mr Rudd is not alone in Abusing Power).
Over decades this had done a great deal to undermine the effectiveness of
Australia's institutions.
For example:
-
political leaders had become content to present opinion
leaders and the electorate with populist policies that had little
prospect of practical outcomes (see
On Populism). As noted above this
apparently
emerged because the increased complexity of the issues governments
address has made it impossible at times to express realistic policy
simplistically;
-
simultaneously elected officials turned their backs
on the 'reality check' on their policy ideas once provided by
professional, independent and experienced public services as a
result of:
-
widespread acceptance of public service politicisation. The result was that political leaders (deliberately or
accidentally) surrounded
themselves with 'yes men' and as a result suffered a loss of contact
with reality and of the fact that not everyone shared their assumptions
(see Decay of Australian Public
Administration). Ironically even political reformers who sincerely
tried to 'reform' bureaucracies to ensure that they had access to
competent advice, were likely to surround themselves with 'yes men' - as
they (predictably) were unable to tell what they didn't know (see
Turning a Blind Eye to
Incompetence and Abuse of Power);
-
applying 'business-like' methods theoretically to lift the efficiency
of governments' often 'non-business-like' functions (see
Governing is Not just Running a Large Business). Business success
is measured by the bottom-line (ie profit), whereas most government
functions suffer market failures that make them too complex to be
assessed in terms of pseudo-commercial outcomes. Attempting to do so resulted in oversimplification in
managing many functions, and fragmentation that
prevented collaboration and the development of the broad
perspective needed to advice properly on broad policy issue. In particular the
application of National Competition Policies arguably had adverse effects on
the ability of government agencies to provide practical policy
advice and support to governments that its economic and academic architects did
not anticipate (see
Neglected Side Effects)
-
federal governments generally presumed that they had Rudd-like wisdom
in relation to functions constitutionally allocated to state governments.
Increasing centralisation of control (made possible mainly by imbalances
in the allocation of responsibilities and access to tax revenues in
Australia's federal system) has led to costly duplication, blame shifting
and serious erosion of the ability of other governments to perform, or be
held democratically accountable, for their nominal functions (see
Federal
State Fiscal Imbalances and
Large doses of (federal)
medicine have been making states sicker). The notion of 'subsidiarity',
(ie that public functions should be allocated to the lowest level of
government able to undertake them in order to ensure community engagement
and effective linkages between functions at a local / regional level) was
ignored. National political leaders increasing sought to micro-manage
functions such as education, health, infrastructure, regional development
without any consideration of the organisational chaos, wastage, breakdown in
coordination; and suppression of initiative that resulted;
- political leaders increasingly sought to present themselves
as moral authorities, the logical end point of which would be to break down the separation
of church and state and put individual liberty (and its political and
economic advantages) at risk (see
above)
This had clearly been foolish.
The inability of central decision makers to acquire the information needed to make
appropriate decisions is the foundation of economists' case for a market
economy (based on Hayek's famous 1945 writing on 'The Use of Knowledge in
Society').
The same constraint applies to centralisation of control and
planning in managing organisations - and this is why central
strategic planning, which was initially adopted by business as a way of coping
with increasingly rapid change in the 1970s, had been largely abandoned in the
corporate world by the 1990s (see
Strategy Development in Business and Government, 1997).
However centralisation of planning and control, which fails because it freezes
out the knowledge, experience, initiative and commitment of all but those at
the centre, has increasingly characterised government in Australia. By 2010
centralization seemed to be viewed by opinion leaders generally as the
'solution of choice' to all presenting problems - though this often only
allowed symbolic claims to be made about dealing with presenting challenges
and opportunities, while nothing much was really achieved.
Failure was not Confined to the Rudd Government
Queensland's Goss Government in the early 1990s, in which Mr Rudd had a
central role, also rendered itself ineffectual by also presuming that central
authorities had super-human wisdom.
As other observers noted, there was nothing significantly different about what
Mr Rudd was doing as Prime Minister and what was done by the Goss Government
in Queensland almost 20 years previously.
Centralised decision making, contempt for cabinet processes, poor
communication and an office run by 'young men in suits' with no real world
experience. This criticism could apply equally to Kevin Rudd's 2 1/2 years
as prime minister and to an earlier stage in his career. Similar concerns
existed about the state Labor government of Wayne Goss in the mid 1990s in
which Mr Rudd was a central player. A review of the Goss Government's loss
of power in 1995 by Mick Young is strikingly similar to the criticisms
directed against Mr Rudd when he was dumped as prime minister. Others have
criticised Mr Rudd's reliance on young, inexperienced advisers. Young spoke
of government being run by Labor loyalists who knew little about other
people. This involved a party in which a chosen few ruled over the alienated
majority. Queensland Labor sources note that while Mr Rudd played a limited
public role in the Goss Government, he was at the centre of government
affairs. Young found that decision making was too centralised, and that
communication with the electorate was poor. (Franklin M.
Rudd reprised errors of Goss Government (The Australian,
2/7/10)
Refusing to listen to advice or the voices of
experience ultimately caused the Goss Government to snatch political defeat
from the jaws of expected victory (see
Queensland's Worst
Government which draws upon the present writer's 1995 submission to
the ALP's review of its electoral failure,
Toward Good Government in Queensland,
1995).
Some claim that Mr Rudd was exceptional in this respect.
Kevin Rudd was
viewed as most influential person in Queensland in 1992 - even though he was
not publicly known or elected. At the time he was head of Cabinet Office,
but had total control of government. This problem of control by un-elected
officials was not new as as a federal minister the power of political
advisers had become very obvious (Cohen B 'Don't vest all power in either PM
or the factions', Australian, 28/6/10)
Kevin Rudd
never listened. This ensured that when he was eventually challenged, he
would quickly lose (Richardson G., 'Fear and loathing of Rudd was all his
own doing', The Australian, 29/6/10)
Presumably it was memory of this electoral debacle in Queensland that led to the
speedy mid 2010 dispatch
of the then prime minister (Mr Rudd) by the federal ALP caucus
Though some claim that Mr Rudd was primarily to blame for this and he seemed
very talented in this respect, presuming 'Rudd-like' wisdom and thus refusing
to listen to the voices of experience seemed to the present writer to
characterise the Goss Government generally. 'Its much simpler than that' was
the standard response from staff in the premier's office when Public Service
staff tried to draw attention to the lessons of their experience.
Moreover in Queensland it was not only the Goss Government that suffered serious failures in
mainstream functions as a result of losing Public Service
competencies and unrealistically centralising machinery for planning and
control.
Consider, for example :
Queensland's government has suffered ongoing crises leading to levels
of public
dissatisfaction that not even the appointment of the state's first female
premier (Anna Bligh) could prevent (eg see
Ballough S etal 'Bligh's battling a toxic poll shock', Courier Mail,
21/6/10)
In 2010, observers started suggesting that Queensland's institutions had
become seriously dysfunctional - ie that the way Queensland was governed and
managed (its governance infrastructure) needed urgent overhaul [1]
And other state governments which implemented packages of 'public management' reforms
similar to the Goss Government also
experienced similar failures, and have ever since been seen to be ineffectual
(most notably the NSW government - see 'It's
time to fix the failed state', 2008).
For example the Cain Government in Victoria
introduced 'reforms' in the 1980s that were apparently copied by the Goss
Government in Queensland in the early 1990s even though Victoria experienced
organisational chaos (see
Review of The Fall of the House of
Cain, 1995) which eventually resulted in an electoral wipe-out
that not even the appointment of Victoria's first female premier (Joan Kirner)
could prevent.
The Greiner Government in NSW and the Kennett
Government in Victoria also experienced unexpected electoral backlashes
similar to that which affected the Goss Government - arguably because their
theoretically-sound policy ideas did not translate into practical benefits.
The same 'public management' approach eventually became firmly established in the federal
government also and seemed likely to result in political leaders who were
surrounded by 'yes men' and in danger of losing touch with practical reality (see The Decay of Australian
Public Administration).
And suggestions emerged soon after Mr Rudd was
displaced as Prime Minister that his successor might exhibit similar behaviour
(ie ignore her cabinet colleagues) [1].
Unstable Government
The Federal election in August 2010 further exposed the looming failure of
Australia's government institutions, and the consequent potential for
political instability.
For example the lack of any significant policy agenda's by either of the major
parties during the election campaign was seen to reflect systemic /
institutional problems.
Example: Ultimately it is the electorate that is to blame for
the poor electoral campaign
(though media and business also have responsibility). While the media covers a
flawed political culture they do not create it. Economics is critical, and
dependent on expert opinion - yet this is much less presented in media than
'spin'. Business contributes by providing self-interested rather than realistic
economic policy options. There is no serious public policy debate - and this is
what cause problems in political system [ 1]
Australia has suffered a failure in its political culture and economic
policy over the past decade. Productivity has gone backwards since 2005
- and living standards would decline if governments were inefficient /
wasteful [1]
An almost 'hung' Parliament resulted in which ultimate victory was
tipped back (by independents) to the existing (ALP) government, even though
its leader
had: (a) suggested that the Government had 'lost its way'; and (b) made
pre-election attempts to 'fix' major sources of public disquiet (eg over people smuggling,
climate change
and the Resource
Super Profits Tax proposal) that were widely seen to be unsatisfactory.
A few observers suggested that the resulting minority ALP Government could
prove effective. Most however seemed to believe that it was likely to be unstable and
ineffectual.
Optimistic ViewsThere is an excellent chance that the new parliamentary make-up will produce
three years of good government. Vested interests will be crushed and important
debates will proceed [1]
The gridlock of the election result has delivered a road map to a more open
Parliament, a less dominant executive and a framework to tackle climate change,
tax reform and the divide between city and country Australia. That is the
potential upside of the election no one won. It must be weighed against the
inherent instability of a minority government without a clear mandate - and an
opposition that believes to its core that it has the greater claim to
legitimacy. [1]
Pessimistic Views
The ALP is broken culturally and philosophically and so would benefit from not
being in government. Australian politics is dominated by trans-national
corporations (eg those who forced Rudd's removal). [1]
Commentators generally believe that it will be hard to govern [1]
Decision about which party should government was reached in way that is inherently unstable
[1
]
ALP gained power with support of outsiders, while large segments of its
electoral base walk away [1]
The task of governing will be very difficult, and no one knows if it will
last. Problem would have been the same for Coalition [1]
There is concern that funds committed for spending in rural areas to gain
the support of independents could delay spending needed elsewhere [1]
The election result "merely marks the beginning of what will become a long
festival of delusion, conspiracy and outright lies – where its hysteria will
only be surpassed by its grubby bitterness and its commercial exploitation" [1].
A hung parliament has been seen as a 'new paradigm', but it is just pork
barrelling by another name [1]
A 'new paradigm' has been proclaimed - but it is so vague it could mean
anything [1]
Bob Brown raised the potentially destabilising prospect of the Greens working
with the Coalition on some legislation [1]
Election outcome produced a government but no guarantee of stability. This is
particularly of concern because of the need for tax reform [1]
Suggestions about a return to tariffs and protectionism make a mockery of
those who have led economic reform in Australia [1]
Because the modern practice of aiming
election campaigns almost exclusively at swinging voters in marginal
electorates - people known to be uninterested in politics, without ideology,
economically illiterate and of a self-centred, what's-in-it-for-me?
disposition - means nothing unpleasant or even faintly serious can be raised.
(Our
economic challenge will be feast not famine , 6/9/10)
Life is going to
be hard for independents no matter which party gains power, because of the
huge amount of work they will need to do in relation to every policy area (Savva
N
'Shackled with a few rogue fence jumpers', Australian, 7/9/10)
Incoming
government will be unable to pursue any reform agenda because of the need to
get agreement from independents who have extravagant wish lists, complex and
varied agendas (Hewett J
'Whatever the verdict, its a recipe for reform stupor', A, 7/9/10)
Despite a lot of talk, reforms vital to Australia's future are unlikely under
Gillard Government. Opponents of economic modernisation and increased
productivity (eg Greens and independents) are ascendant [1]
The fundamental weakness of Gillard Government is already being exposed. The
Greens are able to dominate the policy agenda because positive reactions have
to be given to any proposal they put forward [1]
Observers were also quick to identify similar Opposition weaknesses.
While the Opposition has often highlighted questions about the competence of the
ALP Government, its own competence is suspect in many ways [ 1] A dispute emerged about whether the federal Opposition of the Treasury were
acting unethically in relation to budget estimates [An aside: if one wanted to look for likely 'creative accounting' a
really strong prospect seems to be Queensland's state budget]
The federal Opposition claims about its budget intentions had an $11bn
discrepancy. 'Econocrats' review of this suggested that those budget figures had
been a systematic exercise in creative accounting [ 1] Minutes of meeting between top Canberra bureaucrats which briefed
independents in choosing which party to support, was highly political.
Independents were told that mining tax would not hurt resources boom - a view
not shared by markets. Treasury Secretary said that his tax review had yet to
receive final consideration, though sources suggest that government will not
pursue this. The coalition disputes the biggest item in the claimed $11bn black
hole in its budget estimates, and argues that its estimates are more realistic
than the government's [1]
It was claimed in mid 2011 in relation to the federal Opposition that "The
Coalition is trying to make a virtue of its lack of alternative policies" [1]
And in mid 2011:
As recognition grew that all was not well with
Australia's system of government, some suggested the need for reform of
Parliament (though other suggested that this was of secondary importance).
Independents claim to be interested in Parliamentary reform, but this can't be
taken seriously because of their pork barrelling [ 1]
There is a great deal of interest in reforming Parliament [1]
There is a pressing need for reform of Australia's House of Representatives.
It ranks poorly by international standards. Party-rooms tend to be more
important than the chamber. New parliament house has distanced members from
ministers and one another. Reform needs to make ministers more accountable;
enhance discussion and debate on important issues; and improve scrutiny on
policy and administration. The role of speaker must be stronger, and
question time more effective and dignified. Rules related to questions and
answers need to be tightened. General debate on big issues needs to be allowed.
Parliamentary committees should not be limited to matters approved by ministers.
A Parliamentary budget office is needed (Nethercote J. 'Bringing
the House to order' Australian, 3/9/10)
Australia's governments have long wanted to see themselves as reformers, but
House of Representatives has played no part in this - though Fraser and Hawke
governments made some changes. Televised question period illustrates what people
hate about politics. True debates are non-existent, Committees are useful but
must be discrete. 2010 election outcome has reminded people that House matters (Nethecote
J., 'The House's Day in the Sun arrives', Canberra Times, 7/9/10)
Reform of the House of representatives is not sufficient - changes are also
needed in the Senate (Both houses need renovation,
7/9/`10)
Alternative View
Independents give the impression that Australia's democracy needs root and
branch overhaul. This is wrong as system has worked well. It is important to
avoid adding more red tape. Minority government can work with reliable support
from coalition partner - but not with whims and fancies of those having no
common ideology. Main goal of next government should be to strengthen
Australia's economy - as world is competitive. There is a need to support
private sector and make important reforms to boost productivity and
competitiveness. Now need tax reform; budget surplus; reduced government size;
investment in human capital and infrastructure; sustainable clean energy supply;
better business access to capital; and flexible workplace regulation.
Independents' support should not be accepted if they prevent government
achieving this [1]
However, while there may be a case for reforming the federal Parliament, for reasons suggested above weaknesses in Parliament largely
reflected more fundamental problems (eg increased complexity, erosion of
practical support, ever increased expectations due to centralization of policies
and programs). Moreover, as also noted above, political demands by
some advocates of Parliamentary reform seemed likely to make the overall
machinery of government in Australia less effective (eg see also
More Statesmanship: Less Politics).
In September 2011 the failure of the Gillard Government to achieve practical
outcomes in relation to many issues of public concern made her also the target
of leadership speculations - though leadership change could not solve the
underlying structural problems that constrain government effectiveness.
Resuming rightful roles - email sent 6/9/11
Phillip Adams
Re:
Let Rudd resume rightful role, The Australian, 6/9/11
There is no doubt
that change is needed to government in Australia.
However the
suggestion in your article is unlikely to be helpful. When Mr Rudd was
unceremoniously dumped in favour of Ms Gillard it was realistic to justify this
on the grounds that the ‘government had lost its way’ (see
Starting to Acknowledge Ineffectual Government?). Moreover Mr Rudd had
contributed to this problem (see
Re-considering the Origins of Kevin Rudd’s Failure and
Mr Impractical). And it is understood that many in the ALP choose to blame
Mr Rudd’s autocratic style for the failure of the Goss Government in Queensland
in which he had played a central role (see
Queensland's Worst Government?), and they may have feared a repetition
of that debacle (see
Testing the ALP’s Patience).
However
ineffectual governance probably has structural causes rather than merely being
the fault of particular political leaders. Thus the problem in 2010 was broader
than Mr Rudd (Failure
was not confined to the Rudd Government), just as it is now broader than Ms
Gillard. For example, it was Australia’s whole political system that was
autocratic in neglecting and rejecting the institutional memory (ie knowledge,
experience and wisdom) that professional public services could have brought to
make governments less crisis prone (see
Misunderstanding the Public Service’s Contribution in
Decay of Australian Public Administration).
Speculations
about what might be needed to make government effective again are in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building. The latter
refers (for example) to: the problems facing democratic governments generally
(such as complexity and populism); the difficult international environment; and
artificial constraints on governments’ ability to deal with such challenges (eg
public service politicisation and ever-increasing centralisation of control).
John Craig
In August 2016 after a double-dissolution election had clearly made it
impossible for the federal government to be effective, there was again a
suggestion about the need for reform of Australia's democratic system.
In a world of truncated media cycles, short term policies and fragmented
parliaments, the political world is splintered. However this chaos highlights an
overall pattern of public dissatisfaction with the major parties and their
disconnected way of doing democracy. Major reform of Australia's political and
policy process is needed - because of combative political tactics, a lack of
cooperation in dealing with growing national challenges; poor perceptions of
political leadership; public disconnect / disillusion; increasing roles for
independents. Innovations that might help include: bringing citizens directly
into policy process and citizens' juries / participatory budgeting. This is
based on the view that ordinary citizens are now likely to have as much
knowledge as ministers / departmental experts. This would allow 'ownership' of
the policy outcome. Such changes are being made outside federal sphere - but are
ignored inside. It was true once that those at the top of the policy tree would
have the most relevant knowledge - but this is not so now - so politicians /
bureaucrats and peak group lobbyists are not consistently to best at knowing
what is going on. 19th century representative democracy is increasingly
inadequate - and there is a need for democratic innovation [1]
Unstable Environment
At the same time the international environment posed significant
threats
to Australia that could prove damaging if governments remained ineffectual.
For example, viewed in terms of simple 'economic' data, the economic environment was widely seen
in 2010 to be benign
- and Australia's biggest problem was likely to be managing very rapid growth,
and structural adjustment pressures on other industries (eg manufacturing) and
the regions in which they are concentrated.
Re:
Minority rule about to collide
with booming economy, Weekend Australian, 4-5/9/10Michael
Stutchbury Even if international environment turns nasty Australia's government will be
able to step in with confidence to maintain growth because of its relatively low
debt level (Winestock G., 'Australia's endless economic sunshine', AFR,
4-5/9/10)
However, just as before the global financial crisis emerged, structural features of the international financial system suggested that a crisis was likely which continued ineffectual
government in Australia had the potential to transform into a social and political
disaster. In particular:
- there had been no serious effort to solve problems associated with the
financial imbalances that made continued global economic
growth impossible (see
Unresolved Problems and Coming Crises). The main problem was that 'deficit' countries were
still being relied upon to
be willing and able to continue accumulating public and private debts and this would have to stop
sometime (see
Structural
Incompatibility Puts Global Growth at Risk (2003) and Too Hard for the G20?);
- China's economy (on which Australia had become extremely dependent to
sustain both a commodities export boom and government revenues) appeared
likely to be in difficulties when international financial imbalances could no longer be
sustained. China's economy has a 'Ponzi-like' character. Its growth has depended on
transfers from potential consumers to
fund high levels of state-led investment with little regard to profitability.
Because resource allocation has been based on communitarian consensus
rather than calculations of profitability, those
transfers have had to be very large so that China's financial institutions
would not need to borrow in international financial markets - and this led
to a domestic demand deficit and contributed to unsustainable
international financial imbalances (see Heading for a
Crash). The RBA's warning that Australia was vulnerable to any
downturn in China, and so needed to boost productivity [1],
may be noted;
Moreover those who take a leading role in supporting the Western-style
international economic and political order that is compatible with Australia's
institutions seemed increasingly stressed. For example:
- Europe confronted large losses by financial institutions and the
austerity forced by the high debt levels of some governments - which could
lead to: financial crises; political instability as a result of social
stresses; and demand deficits which impede growth;
- political leadership in the US appeared to be struggling in attempting
to deal with prevailing challenges (eg foreign wars, as well as high
government debts and unemployment). One observer suggested that the US is
so bitterly divided internally, that it is now incapable of providing any
international leadership [1]
An aside: Some suggestions on what those who support
Western-style international institutions (eg the US) might do to improve their
position are included in China
may not have the solution, but it seems to have a problem)
In the event that a global financial / economic crisis were averted
because emerging economies (primarily China) succeeded in creating a new style
of international political and economic order (eg one based, not on
Western-style democratic capitalism, but rather on neo-Confucian
traditions), then Australia would be
confronted with civilizational challenges that it is ill-prepared for (see
Some Thoughts on the 'China Era' and
Lack of Asia Literacy above)
|
A Nation Building
Agenda
|
A Nation Building Agenda [Working Draft]
Australia faces many social, economic, environmental and governmental
challenges and opportunities which require practical actions (eg governments
need to enact
legislation, provide public goods and services while many other types of
organisations need to carry out their functions).
And there are many proposals for what those actions ought to be.
The following suggestions for nation building are not about what 'things'
need to be done, but rather how Australia's governmental, private and community
institutions might be adapted progressively to be more able to
do those 'things' effectively - in a difficult and changing environment.
Such efforts to build stronger institutional capabilities should not be a
precondition for taking practical actions (as this would be a formula for
not achieving much). Rather 'nation building' should be a
result of enabling diverse organisations
to strengthen their capabilities and re-organise as necessary as a result of doing the day-to-day 'things' they
need to do.
'Building the nation' involves making Australia's institutions (eg governments generally; state / local governments
in particular; the political system;
business and community organisations; churches; associations; universities; etc) more
effective in future. To achieve this there is arguably a need for community leaders to :
-
recognise that new challenges, such as those outlined in
this document, require changes to traditional arrangements (eg
consider the impact of increased complexity on the
viability of a core source of the strength of Western societies (ie
rationality),
the damage done to machinery of
government (which has eroded governments' ability to deal with
complexity) and
East Asian influences that are quite different to Western
traditions);
-
liberalize artificial constraints on various institutions, or create legal
frameworks in which they might undertake new functions; and
-
reduce the expectation that the lead in in dealing with major emerging challenges and opportunities
has to be taken by central authorities (as the latter merely results in entertainment for the community with
their ineffectual efforts to
understand, decide and control everything, and constraints on everyone else's ability to
take the rational incremental actions appropriate to their circumstances
that has been the traditional
strength of Western societies).
Constructive initiatives are likely to include:
-
strengthening the ability of independent institutions to increase understanding,
by the community generally and opinion leaders in particular, of complex issues - so that policies are not simply derived from academic
theories, political ideologies, financial considerations, interest group pressure or ignorance (a
suggestion the present writer made
earlier in relation to a national economic reform agenda and also in
Developing Economic Game
Changers).
This is essential because:
- the democratic political process ensures government by
representatives of the people. While this arrangement has many
advantages, the 'man in the street' has difficulty understanding complex
rapidly changing policy issues, and the more that can be done to boost
grass-roots understanding of such issues, the more realistic government
is likely to be;
- there is nothing to be gained (and a
great deal to be lost) by half-baked policy prescriptions that are not based on
consideration of both practical and theoretical aspects of an issue and the
complex relationships mongst public policy issues (eg see
On Populism and
NBN's Bigger Picture). While public
services traditionally provided support to elected governments in
dealing with these complexities, they are no longer able to provide such
a reality check because the trend towards politicisation has resulted in
services dominated by politically-skilled 'yes men';
- basic decisions primarily on financial / pseudo commercial
considerations (as has often been done in the absence of policy wisdom)
is inadequate (see Economic /
Financial Criteria: An Insufficient Basis for Policy);
This might be achieved by:
- directing a small fraction of individuals' / enterprises' taxes to their choice of apolitical institutions that undertake
such tasks in accordance with democratically-endorsed principles;
- encouraging such entities to: (a) reflect diverse types of expertise
and interests; and (b) mobilize
both theoretical and practical competencies;
- encouraging networking amongst such entities, perhaps by those
involved creating an independent Nation Building Foundation with that
role;
- giving increasing precedence (through opportunity exploration
processes operating under democratically approved protocols but without
political accountability) to presenting proposals for responses to strategic
opportunities as indicative plans for initiatives by various community / business
entities with complementary capabilities, rather than simply expecting governments to manage responses; and
-
exposing the practical failures
that are emerging as a consequence of 'post-modern' assumptions that challenge
the perceived relevance of advanced knowledge by: (a) assuming that much social
knowledge is merely a 'construct' to benefit elites; and (b) ignoring the
practical consequences of such knowledge (see also
A Case for Restoring
Universities and Moving
Australia beyond Traditional Multiculturalism);
-
increasing access in particular to realistic assessments of the changing international context,
and of the increasing global significance of 'Asia' in particular.
As noted above, changes in the international
economic environment pose future risks and Australia has a
history of apparently inadequate evaluation of the
implications of such changes.
And Australia's dealings with 'Asia' have been severely hampered by a
lack of strategic Asia-literacy even amongst those who are supposedly most
expert in this area (see Babes in the Asian Woods).
A strategic approach would involve not so much an ability to speak Asia
languages and do business in the region, but rather to understand how
and why Asia (especially East Asia) works as it does (eg see
A Strategic Approach to
Asia-Literacy ).
- simplification of what governments are expected to deal with. This might be
achieved by:
- enabling practical responses to social, environmental and economic challenges
and opportunities to emerge by mobilizing different elements in the
community to support one another without presuming a need for government action or increased red tape
(see below)
- de-concentration of responsibility by constitutional and tax system reforms
suggested in
Fixing Australia's
Federation - though the latter would need to be expanded to take
account of the (perhaps similar) requirements for enabling local
governments also to be effective;
Simplification of what is expected of government is
vital because of the limits to rationality in dealing with complex
systems (and the consequent counter-intuitive and unintended
consequences that can flow from policy action). High levels of
complexity can't be managed by seeking comprehensive analysis so as to
make 'wisdom of Solomon' decisions - but rather requires
de-concentration of responsibility and arrangements to facilitate
better ongoing incremental grass-roots adjustments. This
probably requires: (a) support for enabling the complexity of issues
which cut across various decision centres to be understood; and (b)
empowerment of institutional arrangements which stimulate
collaborative initiative amongst diverse institutions with
complementary roles. The biggest obstacle to creating workable
solutions is the perception that political leaders should be in the
business of making decisions and making things happen (ie
micro-management). If political leaders primary (though by no means
only) role could be viewed as ‘governing’ (ie creating an environment
in which others can make decisions and do things) most of the problem
should disappear.
This applies just as much to government functions as it does to
those within the mainstream economy (where the futility of attempts at
central economic planning has long been recognised).
Attempts have been made for 2 decades to cope with complexity in
government functions by the use of quasi-market processes (ie
competition and commercialization) on the assumption that 'bottom
line' measures can provide a way to coordinate government functions
without the need for policy guidelines. However for mainstream
government functions (ie those subject to serious market failures)
this effort must be, and has proven, counterproductive.
Reinvigoration of the federal system should be a better option for
managing complexity and provide the benefits outlined in
A Federal System has Important
Advantages. The latter refers to: the need for community engagement to reduce the risk of political
instability; the ineffectiveness of centralised planning and control; the
stability promoted by diversity and building on what already works; the
geographic and intellectual isolation of Australia's national capital; the
similar adverse effects of ineffectual past 'reform' on all governments.
In an economic context, this would
(amongst other things) result in systematic efforts to stimulate the
emergence of stronger market-focused industry clusters. Such a capability seems essential to:
- build the
economic productivity and tax base required to prevent the
re-emergence of the long term
steady decline in relative income levels, associated with Australia's
commodity export dependence;
- protect Australia's democratic traditions (see
above); and;
- provide alternatives to
the growth of major existing cities, with the associated congestion and
infrastructure problems (see Re-imagining
Australia's Federation to Build New Cities).
Past attempts to
boost economic productivity and competitiveness by promoting
competition and re-engineering governments as pseudo-businesses are
economically inadequate and have reduced the ability of governments to
actually 'govern' (eg see Impact of
Economic Liberalism in Australia,
Governing is not Just Running a Large Business and
Neglected Side Effects). Moreover
government efforts to directly 'assist' industry have frequently been
counter-productive, through impeding economic development (see
What's wrong with government assistance to fill market gaps).
Complementary changes to Australia's tax system would be needed to
provide state governments with the financial incentive to take economic
development seriously, in order to counteract their political
incentives to interfere in ways that have limited economic benefits (see
below)
Other implications of empowering the exploration and development of
community-based initiatives to address social, economic and environmental issues
would presumably (in the longer term) be a decline in the need for governmental
solutions, and thus in the size of government, taxation and red tape.
-
ensuring that substantial segments of the community don't become alienated / disengaged,
as alienation can
contribute to political instability. This arguably would best be achieved by
encouraging the de-concentration of responsibility as mentioned
above.
The One Nation phenomenon
(see Assessing the Implications of
Pauline Hanson's 'One Nation') illustrates the instability that can result
from alienation. The democratic
process enables such groups to voice their views, and may gives their representatives an insider
view so reducing tensions based on ignorance. However the need to 'educate /
accommodate' the alienated can be disruptive. Thus it is best to ensure that regional /
minority communities are reasonably engaged and informed at all times.
-
re-creation of competent apolitical public services to
support the community's elected representatives - by: providing career protection
from demands for unquestioning acceptance of political ideologies no matter how
naive; emphasising experience as well as
valuing theoretical knowledge;
taking a long term approach to reforms which involves development through normal
operations, rather than 'big bang' reform as a pre-condition for actually doing
anything; paying close attention to the development of a 'public' service
culture (so that the private interests of insiders do not come to dominate as
politicisation is ended); and reconsidering the adverse effect that competition
and 'quasi-commercial' goals have on the ability of government agencies to provide support in undertaking
government's core role (ie governing);
-
clarifying the relationship between the public and private sectors by
privatising functions that can satisfactorily be coordinated through competitive
markets and undertaking functions subject to serious market failures through
public agencies (eg departments / statutory authorities) with widespread use of
contracts in undertaking definable components of those functions.
Where functions that involve serious market failures are privatised, the need
for complex regulation can be highly disruptive (see
Privatization of Monopolies Leading to Regulatory
Failure).
Where such functions are semi-privatised (eg through public private
partnerships): the need for complex regulation can undermine the
benefits potentially gained through greater production efficiency; the
planning and development of integrated infrastructure systems can be
distorted or impossible; and the political process is exposed to moral
hazards (see Problems in the Basic PPP Model)
The erosion of individual morality is leading to serious social symptoms (as
Christianity's traditional 'value-others-as-oneself' ethical ideals are neglected and
apparently increasingly replaced by narrow self interest). In turn this is encouraging political leaders (and others) to claim moral authority to combat those
symptoms and thereby challenge the separation of church and state and / or the
presumption of individual liberty.
Though the primary purpose of churches' evangelical mission is to bring more
abundant life to individuals, widespread success in doing so creates a social
environment characterised by 'responsible liberty' that permits the emergence and maintenance of legal and government institutions that
presume individual liberty and a secular state (ie one that does not claim
religious / moral authority) - see also
Religious
Education: The Need for a Bigger Picture View (2013).
There are reasons to suspect that intellectual obstacles
to Christian adherence, which have increasingly been
eroding the moral foundations of that liberty, can be dramatically reduced.
Firstly the view that scientific understanding of the process of creation
/ evolution discredited Christian cosmology can be seen to be overly
simplistic (eg see
How solid are 'science, reason and
critical thinking'?).
Secondly the post-modern view that 'truth' is
largely a social construct so that all opinions / values are equally valid
can be shown to lead to serious practical failures (see
Confusion of Knowledge).
Cultural assumptions have consequences (ie affect the way societies and
economies work) and the failure of students of the humanities to consider
these out of a desire to be 'tolerant' is arguably the cause of much of
the disadvantage that is suffered and many of the conflicts that arise;
There is arguably no sustainable path to substantial further growth by
Australia's existing major cities because of incompatibilities between the
requirements of effective transport systems and constraints on urban forms (see
comment on structural
obstacles)
-
empowering universities to become more effective, for example as
suggested in
A Case for Restoring
Universities. The latter referred to:
- reducing political demands for emphasis on immediately commercially /
economically relevant outcomes from research, and the managerialist emphasis
on a 'business-like' approach to academics' non-business-like activities;
- addressing confusions that are emerging about the nature and relevance of
knowledge such as those associated with: postmodern assumptions; and the
limitations of rationality, science and philosophy.
The ability of universities to effectively
perform a critical role in contributing to public understanding of
complex opportunities and challenges has (just as occurred with public
services) been compromised by
a naive political desire to force them to boost
economic performance .
Australia's main difficulties in diversification into knowledge
intensive industries lies in a lack of commercial capabilities and organisation
to exploit available opportunities. Political 'push' on 'smart' inputs to that
system (eg R&D) tends to be counter-productive at worst, or pointless at best
(see The Economic Futility of 'Backing Australia's Ability 2'
and
Commentary on Smart State)
The managerialist dominance of universities (ie the view that management is a
generalist function which does not require knowledge of the function being
managed) seems similar to that which pervaded Australia's public services - and
equally dysfunctional (see Decay of Australian Public
Administration).
Governments have placed these obstacle in the path of universities at the
same time that confusion has arisen about the nature of universities' primary
product (see Confusion about
knowledge), and the latter also require attention.
The prospect of providing better institutional support to Australia's
governments was considered earlier in
Restoring 'Faith in Politics'
(2006).
|
Losing What WE Fought For? |
Losing What We Fought For? (email sent 1/5/11)
Terry Sweetman,
Courier Mail
RE:
Wordy retreat founded on poor understanding of what we fought for,
Courier Mail, 29/4/11
In an Anzac Day
context, your article presented a thoughtful case that the legacy of Australians
who have born arms is a nation which has ‘the ability to peacefully redefine’
itself. You also suggested that recognition of same sex marriage is a logical
way now for Australia to redefine itself.
My
interpretation of your article:
God’s warrior, Jim Wallace, followed standard procedure on the cultural
battlefield by apologising for comments on gay marriage and Muslims on Anzac
Day. The boss of the Australian Christian Lobby had said that what Australians
fought for was not gay marriage or Islamic. However this was reversed in the
face of a robust claim that ‘what we fought for was freedom from prejudice and
persecution’. However Wallace quibbled that the Judeo-Christian heritage that
framed the nature of Australia that people fought for is important – and should
be preserved. However the Judeo-Christian heritage has prompted blood-thirsty
clerics in most warring nations. Wallace set himself up as an easy target – but
he is right. Australians didn’t fight for gay marriage or Islam, and the
heritage he speaks of has little to do with ‘freedom from prejudice and
persecution’. Australian servicemen fought against nations and regimes in which
prejudice and persecutions were elements of policy. However Australia has not
been free of these. Australia punished homosexual practices and fostered
sectarianism and discrimination. And racism was deeply entrenched as an element
of policy. Prejudice lingered a long time. One can’t realistically articulate
the diverse and perhaps incompatible motives of those who served. However many
fought for a country, a political system and a civil society that is capable of
mature, rational and peaceful transition. This might not please those who bore
arms and later became conservatives. The country that once persecuted the
sexually different now offers them legal protection. Recognition of same sex
marriage is only a matter of time and political courage. Wallace acknowledged
that people fought for different things, and this is always being redefined.
The ability to peacefully redefine the nation – to make it better, fairer, more
tolerant and more free is the legacy from those who served.
I
should like to submit for your consideration that Australia is in some danger of
losing what you suggest ‘we fought for’ (ie its ‘ability to peacefully redefine
itself’) because the political system is proving ineffectual and civil society
is too weak to do anything about it.
Elaboration:
The
political system is suffering, for example, from: (a) an inability to handle the
complexity of the issues it confronts; (b) purging the professional public
service support required to provide a reality check on foolish policies; and (c)
seeking to win elections on the basis of populist, but ineffectual, policies
(see
Challenge to Democratic Institutions in Australia’s Governance Crisis and
the Need for Nation Building).
The
weakness of civil society is illustrated by, but no means limited to, the lack
of realistic and up-to-date inputs to public policy debates in Queensland that
leaves Executive Governments free of any real constraints from Parliament and
thus able to abuse power, support cronies and be excessively secretive (see
More Competent External Support to Parliament). The latter also suggests
that civil society is weak because there is little depth of understanding of the
institutions Australia inherited (because they were simply taken as given) and
because the community has remained dependent on rich natural assets and copying
policy initiatives from elsewhere in the Anglo-American world. An obsession
with micromanagement by federal governments has also contributed to the
weaknesses of civil society (see
TEQSA: Will Micromanagement Again Triumph over Government?).
Other
sources of risk to Australia’s ‘ability to peacefully redefine itself’ include:
a hazardous lack of Asia literacy; attempts to politicise the role of the head
of state, whose apolitical character is the foundation of the stability of
government; and erosion of the moral foundations of liberal institutions (see
Australia’s Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building).
Finally I suggest that:
John Craig
|
HC Coombs Policy Forum and ANIPP Initiative |
HC Coombs Policy Forum and ANIPP Initiative (email sent
20/6/11)
Dr Mark Matthews,
Executive Director,
HC Coombs Policy Forum
I should like to provide some suggestions in relation to
the arrangements being put in place to improve the flow of information
from
the ANU into the federal public service. My (undoubtedly inadequate)
understanding of what the HC Coombs Policy Forum and ANIPP are intended to do is
primarily based on your
Overview (of HC Coombs Policy Forum) and
The Visioning Australia’s Future Initiative
My comments in turn are based on four decades of strategic
policy R&D in relation to Queensland’s development (including being credited in
the 1980s with forcing the Queensland Premier’s Department to establish a formal
policy function for the first time). That experience has resulted in:
- a need to consider the way in which governments, communities and
economies ‘learn’, giving rise to suggestions about how that process might be
enhanced, eg see
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (from 2003)
and
Curing Queensland's Myopia (2011);
- observation of what actually happened in Queensland (which while
anything but Australia’s best practice demonstrates lessons that have broader
relevance). In particular:
- The ‘informed’ community (ie those with pretentions to advise
governments on policy) was initially decades out of date in terms of policy
issues, while government itself was about 15 years out of date. It was always
easy in the 1980s to find international sources that provided better and more
up-to-date options about almost anything. Innovations took 15 years to be
adopted because: (a) 5 years was required to formalize conclusions through
international institutions such as OECD; (b) another 5 was required for
understanding / acceptance of this by Commonwealth; and (c) another 5 years was
needed for transmission to Queensland Government (including overcoming the drag
effect of decades-out-of-date community opinion). There was thus a clear option
to speed up the process by cutting out the middlemen, and getting the ‘informed’
community engaged in the process;
- There was little interaction between academia and government, and
little immediate benefit from increasing the flow of research ideas from
academia to government because: (a) academia suffered to an extent from the same
‘out of date’ problem as the ‘informed’ community generally and did not have
awareness of practical aspects or of the complexity of issues; and (b) it was
possible to generate more up-to-date and appropriate options by study of
international experience and sources;
- A reformist government in the early 1990s (the Goss
administration) adopted ideas that had been generated in academia (mainly in the
Griffith University) as the basis for widespread change in Queensland’s
Government. Those ideas were apparently heavily influenced by problems facing
the Whitlam Government in the 1970s and the resulting work of the Royal
Commission on Australian Government Administration. The combined effect of: (a)
the adoption of policy ideas that had been ‘stewing’ in academia for years ; and
(b) a lack of practical awareness of what was required for effective government
and the actual functions of government led to a disaster from which Queensland
has not yet recovered (see
Toward Good Government in Queensland 1995 and
Queensland's
Worst Government?, 2005). Idealism that is not moderated by practical
considerations is not always useful. Similar damage to government Australia-wide
has apparently resulted from the adoption of idealistic policy which is not
moderated by the practical experience of a politically-independent professional
public service (eg see
Decay of Australian Public Administration, 2002 and
On Populism).
From that standpoint I should like to submit the following
for your consideration in relation to some issues raised in your documents:
- It is encouraging to see such analysis being undertaken of the
way in which interchange of information can be expedited;
- There is no doubt that ideas that might be the basis of innovation
are of most value early rather than later. This can be illustrated in relation
to innovations of potential economic relevance as in
Economic Solutions appear to be beyond politics (and the associated
diagram). The point is that to really benefit from commercially-relevant
ideas, they need to be transmitted to practitioners before being officially
politically accepted. Political acceptance can’t happen until ideas have already
been widely adopted, and thus ceased to provide potential competitive advantages
(and this is one of the reasons that central economic planning is impossible).
This point is not as obviously relevant to policy options, until it is
recognised that government overall is as complex as the economy, so that
centrally ‘planned and controlled public policy can be just as inappropriate as
it can be for the economy. A formal accountability process requiring central
control of policy may be highly dysfunctional, and a justification for reform
rather than a justification for better informing those at the centre;
- improving the exchange of information between the ANU and the
federal public service (while useful) is a very limited goal in relation to what
is probably needed because:
- there is an unavoidable ‘ivory tower’ element to both these
institutions (especially in an environment in which holding senior public
service positions depends on conformity with political expectations rather than
deep knowledge and long experience of the practical requirements for effective
policy);
- simply getting research results to the public service is of
limited relevance because of the latter’s political responsiveness, and because
Australia’s political system reflects what is known by a significant segment of
the ‘informed’ community. Thus no matter what public servants know political
acceptance is more likely to be boosted by improving understanding in the
‘informed’ community. And if ‘insiders’ gain understanding of policy options and
get political agreement to implement these while much of the
‘should-have-been-informed’ community has no idea what is going on or ability to
cope with the outcome the result can be politically disruptive – as illustrated
by the ‘One Nation’ phenomenon (see
Assessing the Implications of Pauline Hanson's One Nation, 1998);
- the prevailing expectation that responses to challenges and
opportunities will be primarily orchestrated through Australia’s federal
government is a significant factor in problems in governing Australia at
present. As suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building complexity is
a major constraint. Complexity can’t be handled through the rational processes
for problem solving that have been the
basis for success in recent centuries by Western societies, and complexity
is increased by centralisation;
- there is arguably a great deal to be gained by reducing
complexity and reliance on political understanding in responding to some
challenges and opportunities by: (a) de-centralisation of responsibility for
government actions; and (b) democratically empowering some apolitical
institutions to take new roles without direct political accountability – and
this is what is suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building;
- there are limitations in a ‘balance sheet’ approach to
evaluating policy options that seems to feature in
The Visioning Australia’s Future Initiative, because convention
economics arguably requires major adjustments to cope with current conditions
(see
The Advantages and Limitations of Financial Criteria). For example, while
presenting meaningful ‘accounts’ is highly desirable, information must be used
to change what people do as well as to predict what will happen. A primary
emphasis on using information to change behaviour (rather than providing
information as the basis for rational decisions about ‘accounting’ outcomes) is
a key feature of the neo-Confucian systems of socio-political-economy that have
allowed rapid modernisation in East Asia (see
East Asia in Competing Civilizations), and also perhaps a major
obstacle to their ongoing success (see
Are East Asian Economic Models Sustainable?);
- there would, more generally, be value in seeking an
Asia-literate approach to what ANU and the federal public service are attempting
to do, because in the absence of this policy initiatives that seem very
sound on a conventional basis may be dangerous (see
Babes in the Asian Woods and
Comments on Australia's Strategic Edge in 2030).
I would be
interested in your response to the above speculations.
John Craig
|
Why ALL politicians need better advice, and what is needed for
them to get it |
Why ALL politicians need better advice, and what is needed for them to get it -
email sent 7/2/12
Rob Burgess
Business Spectator
RE:
The 'real' Julia needs new advisors, Business Spectator, 7/2/12
Your article suggested that there are deficiencies in the
advice that Australia’s current prime minister is receiving. However she is
anything but alone in this respect. Moreover the problem seems to be structural
rather than being the fault of a few particular individuals (ie those
deficiencies arguably reflect weaknesses in the institutional support to
Australia’s political system both inside and outside the public sector).
Ms Gillard assumed the role of prime minister because she
had argued successfully that a change in leader was necessary because ‘the
government had lost its way’. However it seems that the Government’s ‘way
remains lost’, and few seem to believe that the Opposition has ‘found its way’.
Some suggestions about the nature of the structural
problems that make it hard for Australian’s elected representatives to ‘find
their way’ and what might be done to improve the situation are in
The Need for Nation Building and
A Nation Building Agenda (which are sections added in 2008 to
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+).
John Craig
|
Creating an Environment for National Political Leadership |
Creating an Environment for National Political Leadership -
email sent 30/5/12
Michael Gawenda,
Centre for Advanced Journalism
University of Melbourne
Re:
Longing for a courageous leader, Business Spectator, 30/5/12
Your article pointed to obvious current limitations in the
quality and effectiveness of political leadership in Australia.
I would like to submit for your consideration that there
are structural reasons for these problems, such as the increasing complexity of
the issues governments face that is not being matched by the better support that
the political system needs to cope with a more complex environment (see
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+).
Some suggestions about what might allow these limitations
to be overcome are in
Australia's Next Successful Prime Minister (2012).
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Fixing Australia's Broken Democracy |
Fixing Australia's Broken Democracy -
email sent 9/6/12
Professor Peter Van Onselen,
University of Western Australia
Re:
The royal reason our system is broken, The Australian, 9/6/12
I should like to try to add value to your excellent
article.
Your suggestion about a constitutional debate like that in
the late 19th century seems extremely worthwhile. Issues related to
the head of state and federal state relationships need to be considered properly
(ie through more than a brief talk-fest), because:
- Advocacy of, and opposition to, the shift to a republican system
seems to have been conducted without any serious consideration of how such a
system would work – and politicisation of the role of the head of state (eg via
direct election) would risk future political instability unless accompanied by
many other constitutional changes (see
Republican Realism: A Purely 'Ceremonial' Head of State?, 2010);
- Further centralisation of power within Australia’s system of
government would, as your article suggests, probably make a bad situation worse
(see
Fixing Australia's Federation, 2010).
There have recently been various comments on a survey which
suggested that young Australians are losing interest / faith in democracy as an
effective system of government (eg see Callick R.,
Relativism eroding faith in democracy, The Australian, 5/6/12). This
is hardly surprising as a loss of confidence in democracy has been emerging for
decades (eg see
Challenges to Australia’s Democratic Institutions).
However Australia’s system of government is ‘broken’ in
many ways that go beyond the dysfunctional federal system that your article
mentioned and the ‘relativism’ that Rowan Callick drew attention to. Some
suggestions about those causes (and others, as well as possible remedies) are
offered in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+). And
some suggestions about the possible requirements to restore effectiveness to
democracies in a global context are outlined in
Saving Democracy.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Running Repairs to the Ship of State |
Running Repairs to the Ship of State - email sent 16/2/13
Peter van Onselen,
University of WA
Re:
PM's in check, now Shorten must move, The Australian, 15/2/13
While I have no idea whether (as your article suggested) it
is up to Mr Shorten to decide the best way to rejuvenate the federal government,
I should like to submit that there is a need for much more than choosing who
should sit in which particular chair on Australia’s unseaworthy ship of state as
it sails through hazardous waters.
The current prime minister assumed that role because it
seemed clear to insider observers in 2010 that ‘the government had lost its way’
(see
Recognising a Need for Nation Building). However the problems in Australia’s
government that then threatened the ALP with electoral annihilation were not
just due to the failings of her predecessor, but were more the result of
structural defects that have made Australia’s ship of state unseaworthy.
Some undoubtedly-improvable speculations about those
defects were outlined in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+). The
latter referred, for example, to:
- The ever-increasing complexity of policy issues, which has made
effective public debate (the foundation of democratic politics) much less
realistic, and has favoured insubstantial political populists;
- Politicisation of public services to ensure ‘responsiveness’ – a
‘reform’ that had the unintended effect of inhibiting reality checks on poor
policies;
- Requiring competition and commercial practices in the hope that
this would boost efficiency in the provision of public goods - a ‘reform’ that
was often counter-productive because many government functions are subject to
serious market failures, and cross-functional collaboration is critical to
enabling governments to deal with complexity;
- Fiscal imbalances within Australia federal system which lead to:
(a) duplication and increased complexity / costs; (b) distortion of state
administrations; (c) suppression of initiative; (d) and overly-simplistic policy
prescriptions - because central planning of public functions must fail (just as
central economic planning fails) because central authorities must lack access to
enough of the required information.
A serious commitment to running repairs to Australia’s ship
of state, perhaps along the lines suggested in
A Nation Building Agenda, would be more useful than worrying about who is
sitting in the captain’s chair.
John Craig
|
Moving on: Good Idea but Not Easy |
Moving on: Good Idea but Not Easy - email sent 26/3/13
Professor Marilyn Lake,
University of Melbourne
Re:
It's time - for the 'old men' of the ALP to move on, Brisbane Times,
26/3/13
There is no doubt that it was time for some theories about what is
needed to ‘fix Australia’ to be discarded – eg for
reasons suggested in relation to recent proposals by a Commission of Audit for
‘fixing Queensland’.
However throwing out the ‘old’ (and it is noted that there are many
parallels between the ‘old’ ideas of the ALP and those of the Opposition) is no
use unless one is very certain that the ‘new’ is not only desirable but also
workable. And, as implied in the comments mentioned above, there is a need to
strengthen the institutional support to Australia’s political system if
desirable outcomes are to be both realistic and competently implemented.
Speculations about what achieving such outcomes might require in a
national context are outlined in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+)
– and briefly outlined in
Running Repairs to the Ship of State (2013). These reforms would be
neither easy nor quick to put into practice, but would be essential if ‘new’
policy options are not to be sabotaged by the institutional incompetence that
has increasingly plagued governments across Australia.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Is 'Policy Heroism' the Answer? |
Is 'Policy Heroism' the Answer? - email sent 28/3/13
Annabel Hepworth
The Australian
Re:
'Heroics' needed on major projects, says Tony Shepherd, The Australian,
28/3/13
While the business leaders you quoted were
undoubtedly correct in identifying the need for infrastructure investment,
encouraging more ‘heroic reforms’ by the federal government (which would
probably generate unexpected and dysfunctional side effects) was not a very good
idea.
My interpretation of your article:
BCA President (Tony Shepherd) has urged
the federal government to show leadership in fixing infrastructure shortfalls –
rather than managing a ‘genteel decline’ in prosperity. A growing infrastructure
backlog is eroding competitiveness, increasing cost-of-living pressures and
lowering quality of life. Past ‘heroic reformers’ have been succeeded by those
who are more cautious. New approaches are needed to reduce health costs – and
federal Treasurer was wrong to criticize Queensland’s contracting-out approach
to clinical health services. Much remains to be done in relation to
infrastructure (eg asset sales and fundamental reform to the cost of service
delivery to unlock funds for new productivity-enhancing projects). The federal
government’s plan to pump $20bn into nation-building projects had been hampered
by GFC. All state-governments are cash strapped (especially Queensland and SA).
The federal government could borrow cheaply – and productive opportunities are
available. Government’s infrastructure tsar (Rod Eddington) described a
‘disconnect’ between people’s concerns about infrastructure and a reluctance to
raise taxes. Infrastructure must either be funded by government or by user-pays.
Federal Labor has baulked at user-pays – but faces pressure from business to
encourage infrastructure provision and to use the budget to fill the void left
by dumping of resources projects. BCA expects federal infrastructure funding to
become more important as state budget limits are reached. Federal Labor set up
Infrastructure Australia which has a solid list of projects worth funding, and
the Opposition has supported the need for ‘cranes’ and ‘bulldozers’. There is a
need to ‘change the game’ on infrastructure – with national leadership.
There are much broader problems that need
to be fixed in Australia’s system of government and those problems are largely
(though not only) a by-product of past ‘heroic reforms’ that have helped to make
government machinery more-or-less unworkable.
It is submitted for your consideration
that:
- severe problems in Australia’s machinery for the planning and
development of infrastructure have been obvious for many year (eg see
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy, 2005). The latter
referred amongst other things to: federal / state fiscal imbalances; and
fragmentation of responsibility and loss of competencies within states as part
of earlier ‘heroic reforms’;
- Making up a list of projects through Infrastructure Australia that
might be worth funding (but would probably further fragment and dislocate
Australia’s machinery for planning and developing infrastructure) is less useful
than encouraging that group to look at the mess that infrastructure machinery
has become (see
Infrastructure Magic?, 2008);
- the ‘heroic reforms’ currently being attempted by the Queensland
Government (including contracting out clinical services) are based on a desire
to do something about real problems, but they involve trying to apply
business-like methods that:
- while there may well be a need for increased infrastructure
spending (possibly financed by government) to boost Australia’s economy in the
post-resources boom era, it needs to be recognised that the global economy seems
currently to be being driven by quantitative easing by reserve banks which is
primarily stimulating ‘growth’ by enabling government debts to rise to
unsustainable levels - especially in Japan, China and the
US (see
Debt Denial: Stage 3 of the GFC?). There is a need to consider that context
in making decisions about how Australia should respond to the end of the
resources boom in an environment in which fundamental structural defects in the
global financial system remain in the ‘too hard’ basket (eg see
G20 in Washington: Waiting for Hell to Freeze Over?);
- options for boosting Australia’s economy (and thus the tax base
and government revenues) need to be considered in assessing governments’ fiscal
capacity (eg see
Comments on Dow's Advanced Manufacturing Plan for Australia);
- there is arguably more to be gained by the decentralisation of
responsibility than by expecting the federal government to take ‘heroic’
initiatives that inhibit decentralised incremental initiatives (see
Centralization is Part of the Problem: Not the Solution). De-concentration
could be part of the ‘nation building’ needed to genuinely reduce the risk of a
‘genteel decline’ in prosperity (see also
Running Repairs to the Ship of State).
John Craig
|
Increasing Governmental Incompetence via A Federal Commission of
Audit? |
Increasing Governmental Incompetence via A Federal Commission of Audit? - email sent 4/4/13
Tom Dusevic
The Australian,
Re:
Bureaucracy to be laid bare in audit, The Australian, 3/4/13
Your article suggests that the federal opposition, if
elected, would launch a commission of audit to examine the quality of all
government outlays (and that this would, amongst other things help identify the
cause of the huge growth in the number of executives in the federal
bureaucracy).
I should like to suggest, however, that a commission of
audit would be a seriously inadequate way of addressing the many problems that
afflict Australia’s federal government because such a commission would: (a)
address those diverse and interconnected problems from only one (ie a financial)
point of view; and (b) perhaps encourage a future government to issue edicts
that do a great deal of damage because of factors that are well known within the
bureaucracy but unrecognised by the commission because of its narrow terms of
reference. These points are developed in more detail in relation the inadequacy
of a recent commission of audit in Queensland (Reforming
State Governments: Does Queensland's Commission of Audit Have the Answer?).
The latter argues that more could be achieved by giving
attention to financial issues in a broader context ie by dealing with financial
constraints as one issue amongst many while: (a) getting on with the job of
governing competently; and (b) recognising that doing so will be impossible
without enhanced institutional support (eg as suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+).
There is absolutely nothing new about narrowly focused
inquiries doing a great deal of damage to Australia system of government (see
Decay of Australian Public Administration, 2002 ) and considerable evidence
of the resulting dysfunctions (see
Towards a Professional Public Service, 2001)
John Craig
|
National Plan for School Improvement: An Example of Bad Policy? |
National Plan for School Improvement: An Example of Bad Policy? - email sent 15/5/13
Gene Tunny
Queensland Economy Watch
Re:
Long-term education target unlikely to be met – haven’t we
learned from previous unachievable targets?, 15/5/13
Your article realistically suggested that:
- directing funding to the school system is no guarantee of
achieving the desired educational outcomes; and
- it is strange that the Commonwealth is committing to a highly
ambitious target in an area in which the states play the most important role.
However the situation is arguably even worse than this,
because the National Plan for School Improvement (which evolved from the Gonski
Review) seemed to be:
- Concerned with very real problems – namely the growing incidence
of social disadvantage in various communities; and
- Trying to remedy the problems through improved education - even
though the problem has many causes most of which can’t be affected by increasing
education spending.
Moreover throwing huge quantities
of special purpose funding in the direction of state-run schools will inevitably
exacerbate the effectiveness and efficiency problems that are implicit in
Australia’s federal fiscal imbalances (ie buck passing, duplication and complex
administration).
These points are further
developed in
Comments on The Gonski Review.
John Craig
|
Get Ready for Coalition Chaos |
|
Beyond 'Negative' and 'Celebrity' Politics |
Beyond 'Negative' and 'Celebrity' Politics - email sent 11/6/13
Kylie Lang
Qweekend
Re:
Political leaders must give us reasons to care, Sunday Mail, 9/6/13
Your article suggested that voters want political leaders
who they can believe in. However what voters really need is for the ‘political
leaders they believe in’ to be able to govern competently. For years the
electorate has been: (a) oblivious to serious weaknesses that have been emerging
in government machinery; and (b) willing to support celebrity populists (ie
those who proffer ‘something to believe in’ that is not realistic).
My
interpretation of your article: Australia
needs a true leader. Without this people are apathetic about politics. A coming
change of government is not interesting, as the Opposition has done nothing but
oppose. Voters want substance, not celebrity – a clear path to progress backed
by sensible affordable policies. In 1942 Menzies outlined a direction for
Australia after WWII. He believed that a thriving democracy required an
aspirational middle class – and thus called on men returning from war to not be
‘boneless wonders’. He called for active citizenship. However Australia is now
more politically demotivated than ever. ANU studies have shown a declining
interest in politics by younger people. They are very concerned about political
issues, but have no faith in politicians championing them. Young people are
using social media (rather than joining political parties) to support causes. Dr
Martin Aaron says that under 30s are sick of waiting for politicians to stop
bickering. Civic participation may be better through groups such as Australian
Youth Climate Coalition, OurSay, Young and Well Cooperative Research Centre and
Foundation of Young Australians. Politicians need to pay attention to such
groups.
The constraints on the effectiveness of Australia’s
political system are primarily structural rather than simply a lack of visionary
leaders. The complexity of issues has increased dramatically. The professional
support needed to provide a reality check on, and successfully implement,
political policies has been eroded by politicisation of public services and
changes that it was hoped would increase the efficiency of service delivery. The
international environment has changed in ways that are not well understood, and
there is a lack of machinery to gather the strategic intelligence to operate in
that environment. Australia has traditionally not needed well developed civil
institutions to formulate up-to-date and realistic policies – because of past
dependence on both natural resource wealth and copying policy initiatives from
other OECD countries. These and other issues (as well as the sorts of
institutional changes that may be needed to make government effective) are
speculated in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+).
In what is degenerating into an increasingly unworkable
institutional setting, political leaders can’t manufacture the ‘substance’ that
you suggest is needed (ie a clear path to progress backed by sensible affordable
policies). Almost all that they can offer to gain electoral support is
‘negativity’ (ie evidence of others’ failings) or ‘celebrity’ (eg simplistic but
insubstantial promises to fulfil the community’s dreams – see
On Populism, 2007+).
In 2010 Australia’s political system came close to
recognising that there was a fundamental problem (see
Recognising a Need for Nation Building). However the need to do more than
replace a populist prime minister was not recognised and political gamesmanship
soon re-asserted itself.
Illustration: This can be
illustrated by the relatively ‘easy to understand’ but inadequate policy
proposals that are being advanced (by the federal Government and Opposition
respectively) to deal with very complex policy challenges - see
National Plan for School Improvement: An Example of Bad Policy? and
Increasing Governmental Incompetence via A Federal Commission of Audit?. One
dimensional responses (eg through education funding or fiscal constraint) can’t
deal effectively with all-too-real problems that have multiple dimensions, and
thus require that many different approaches be able to be taken simultaneously
by many different groups (eg by citizens, families, civil society as well as
multiple levels of government and multiple agencies each of which has different
functions). It is worth remembering that it is not possible to define ‘easy to
understand’ answers for the future of an economy – and that this is why market
arrangements are put in place so that those answers can be found by
decentralised incremental initiative.
A rethink of who is supposed to do what is needed before it
is likely that political leaders will be able to be effective in making the
contribution that the electorate expects of them.
Until this is done the electorate will continue to be
frustrated. There is certainly a need for groups like those mentioned in your
article to try to put forward the best possible policies. But without a serious
(and incremental) commitment to institutional change, Australia’s politicians
will be unable to achieve what is really needed no matter how good their
policies may sound to the electorate.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Restoring Political Competence is Becoming Urgent |
Restoring Political Competence is Becoming Urgent - email sent 28/6/13
Annabel Crabb
ABC
Re:
Questions Kevin Rudd now has to answer, The Drum, 27/6/13
Your article noted that Mr Rudd’s press statement following
his re-election to lead the ALP started by acknowledging that
"in recent years, politics has failed the Australian
people". He never said a truer word,
though this problem has been developing for decades rather than just arising ‘in
recent years’.
The now-officially-recognised failure of Australian ‘politics’ is
primarily a systemic problem (eg related to changes that have rendered the political process and
government machinery less effective). It is not simply the fault of particular individuals or
groups, and can’t be fixed simply by replacing those who are seen to have
‘failed’ with others (eg replacing Mr Rudd with Ms Gillard in 2010, or replacing Ms
Gillard with Mr Rudd in 2013).
Moreover the need to deal with those systemic problems and
restore competence to Australia’s political institutions is becoming urgent
because international financial, economic and security risks are increasing.
The above points
are developed further on my web-site, and I would be interested in your response to
my speculations.
John Craig
Elaboration
Systemic Obstacles to Effective Politics
Australia's ‘politics’ is failing largely because changing
circumstances and the unintended consequences of past reforms have made it much
harder to identify constructive policies and have them implemented competently.
Examples:
Changing circumstances include increased complexity and the inadequacy of of
simply continuing to copy US / UK policy precedents; while the public sector’s ability to handle
complexity and provide a reality check on policy has been eroded (eg by
politicisation and by attempts to make governments more business-like in
carrying out their non-business-like functions).
Dysfunctional Outcomes: Many dysfunctions have arisen
domestically from a desire to impose simple /
easily comprehensible / politically saleable 'solutions' to multi-dimensional
problems (ie to problems that have aspects that are not improved (or potentially
made much worse) by remedies that take account of only one or two of those dimensions). For example:
- attempt to 'reform' government machinery to make it more politically
responsive or 'efficient' in the delivery of public goods and services have
seriously reduced the ability of governments to govern or provide public
goods and services effectively (eg see
Decay of Australian Public Administration and
Neglected Side Effects of National
Competition Policy);
Political idealism needs a 'reality filter':
Governments deal with many complex and highly inter-related
issues - and their primary function (governing) involves creating a framework
for social and economic activities within the community. Governing requires a depth
of knowledge, experience and wisdom that is quite different to that associated
with the provision of public goods and services - and the latter also require a
depth of knowledge, experience and wisdom because they are
typically subject to serious market failures and thus can't be provided effectively on a
pseudo-commercial basis (because of their non-commercial relationships with other
functions).
The machinery of government
that Australia inherited from the UK embodied arrangements (eg via a permanent
professional public service; collegiality; and formal cabinet / budgetary
processes) to support elected governments. The latter's policy agendas might
address (say) 100 current issues, and these had to be integrated with the thousands of policy issues related to
both governance and service delivery that were current at some time in the past.
Traditional public service arrangements provided support in doing this - but
not because public servants were
particularly smart. Rather government machinery embodied a huge amount of
‘tacit’ knowledge (ie knowledge that was implicit rather than anything that anyone could put
into words). It was embodied in: (a) the diverse knowledge and experience of
practitioners in many functions; (b) the things they did and the way they did
them in response to many long-forgotten needs or policies; (c) the way the
overall system operated to try to take account of the across-the-board
implications of new policy proposals; and (d) exploration of future needs and
options without necessarily being bound by the limitations of politics.
Government machinery (including the decision making role of elected politicians
to bring in community knowledge and perspectives) was a sort of ‘computer’ that
dealt with very complex issues. That 'computer' included a 'reality
filter' (via a permanent / apolitical professional public service) through which
populist political idealism would be passed - thereby altering
/ eliminating
ideas that were unlikely to work in practice. That 'computer's' ability to support
elected governments in both governance and the provision of goods and services
has been seriously disrupted over recent decades as a result of 'reforms' implemented by those with narrow agendas
and little
or no knowledge or experience of the nature or functions of government.
- attempts to deal with the fiscal challenges that governments
increasingly face through commissions of audit have also involved
overly-simplistic assumptions about the difficulties of adequately
supporting elected governments - because while financial considerations are
important they are only one amongst many considerations that are needed in
making decisions about changes in government (eg see
Reforming State Governments: Does Queensland's Commission of Audit Have the
Answer?);
- the establishment of Infrastructure Australia in an attempt to define
priority projects for federal government financial support involved the
naive assumption that such projects could be identified and implements in
relative isolation from the diverse other functions that they were related
to (see
Infrastructure Magic?);
- the Gonski educational reform agenda appears to be directed towards
solving very real problems - namely systematic educational under-achievement
in various regions. However the problem has multiple causes, and can't be
resolved through a single-dimensional 'solution' (ie more spending on, and
control of, education by the federal government) - see
comments on the
Gonski review
Serious failures have also arisen from a lack of strategic
understanding of the international environment and Australia's traditional reliance
on the UK and the US who are also struggling to understand a changing world
(because the humanities and social science faculties of their universities,
like those in Australia, have not yet seriously considered the
practical consequences of differences in
cultural assumptions). For example:
- Australia participated in US-led military action in Iraq and Afghanistan in
order to counter security threats posed by Islamist extremists - though the
military / security 'solution' that was the US preference was an
overly simplistic response to a much more complex
challenge (eg 'freedom from oppression' by Saddam Hussein's regime was
not sufficient to ensure peace and prosperity in a country such as Iraq because the cultural and institutional preconditions that 'free'
societies depend on were not present);
- It was naively assumed that an 'Asia century' would involve
international diplomatic and relationships that operated under Western
principles (see Australia in the Clayton's
Century).
A more comprehensive account of
the emergence of systemic obstacles and speculations about what might be
required for a solution is in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+).
The latter
outlines the need for, and possible means of achieving, nation building initiatives that should
help restore the competence of Australia's
democratic political institutions - initiatives such as:
- Increasing the ability of community generally and opinion leaders in
particular to understand: complex policy issues; the international context
(Asia in particular); and that complexity can render simple-sounding
'solutions' ineffective;
- Simplification of what governments have to deal with;
- Democratically empowering apolitical institutions to accelerate the
development of community-based or market-based support to individuals /
enterprises;
- De-concentration of responsibilities to ensure that large segments of the
community don’t become alienated / disengaged;
- Re-creation of competent apolitical public services;
- Clarifying the relationship between public and private sectors;
- Reminding churches that strong Christian foundations are needed for liberal
legal and governmental institutions like those in Australia;
- Empowering state and local governments to be more effective (eg by changes
to tax regimes);
- More rapid market-driven growth of regional centres;
- Empowering universities to be more effective.
Australia’s political system has been floundering for
several decades and the cumulative effect is becoming serious (ie Australia has
been headed down a ‘banana republic’ path). The electorate has faced a choice
between:
- political populists who achieve electoral support by proposing grand
programs and projects - even though the latter may achieve little of
practical value and be very expensive (see
On Populism);
- those who look better only because of their predecessors
failures but have little or no adequate policy agenda - and sometimes spend
their entire term undertaking umpteen inquiries that often can't really
identify viable programs or projects because they are narrowly focused.
The environment increasingly favours political confidence tricksters of
dubious character and limited talent who gain electoral support from grandiose
promises because of the lack of any realistic / competent alternative.
Simply changing governments (or the personalities who
dominate within governments) on the basis of their ‘popularity’ with the
electorate cannot restore competence in the face of the systemic obstacles that
exist. The situation can only be improved by political leaders who are willing
to address the systemic obstacles as part of the process of implementing the
political priorities of the day.
A case for dealing with systemic obstacles was outlined in
more detail in
Australia's Next Successful Prime Minister (2012). The latter pointed
to:
- weaknesses in external and internal support to Australia’s
democratic political institutions in developing policy;
- obstacles to competent policy implementation (eg public service
politicisation and attempts at centralised micro-management of issues that are too complex
to be dealt with that way); and
- the risk that a deteriorating international economic environment
could pose threats to Australia’s economic, employment and public-revenue
growth.
The Urgency of Restoring Political Competence
Restoring competence in Australia’s political system is
becoming ever more urgent because of the escalating international financial,
economic and security risks that Australia is confronting. Some of the
instabilities and market changes that require domestic economic adjustments are
reasonably obvious on the basis of conventional economic analysis. However
analysis which takes account of structural incompatibilities between competing
cultural and economic systems (eg as suggested in
The Infantile US vs China
Debate) suggests that the risks may be far greater than is
widely recognised.
Though the situation changes from day to day a flavour of the
problem is illustrated by:
-
Debt Denial: Stage 3 of the GFC? - which highlighted financial system
obstacles to the global economic recovery that had been hoped for in early
2013;
-
Fasten Seat Belts: Rough Weather Ahead - which highlighted increasing
tensions in East Asia and the relationship between these and a 'clash of
civilizations' that is particularly reflected in incompatible financial systems;
-
Credit Bust First: 'Sixth Revolution' Later - which referred to the attempts
that have been made by quantitative easing to create a sustainable basis for
global growth and to the emerging conclusion that: (a) this is doing more
harm than good; and (b) unwinding this is likely to be seriously disruptive.
The core problem is that high debt levels have grown as a by-product of
attempts to solve structural problems in the global economy with counter-cyclical policies; and
-
Australia's Hazardous Foreign Liabilities in an Unstable International
Environment - which referred to risks that Australia faced at the start of
the GFC which have been moderated by domestic changes, but escalated by the
international financial / economic risks that are now emerging.
|
Australia's Political System |
Australia's Political System - email sent 30/8/13
Barry Jones
Re:
Barry Jones: the 2013 election and the death of rationality, The
Conversation, 29/8/13
I noted with interest your observations
about the poor quality of recent election campaigns and the increasing evidence
of lightweight populism.
Some suggestions that these problems have
systemic (and thus potentially correctable) causes are in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+). The
latter refers, for example, to:
- the increased complexity (interconnection) of policy issues which
often makes simple explanations impossible;
- inadequacies in the support available to the political system in
dealing with complex issues related to: (a) weakness that have historical roots
in the civil institutions needed to promote realistic public understanding; and
(b) politicisation of public services;
- the rise of populism (see also
On Populism, 2007+);
- Institutional changes that should help to reduce these systemic
problems.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Navel Gazing Certainly Can't Solve the ALP's Problems |
Navel Gazing Certainly Can't Solve the ALP's Problems - email sent 2/9/13
Frank Bongiorno
ANU
Re:
Hearts, heads and pockets, Inside Story, 2/9/13
Your article speculated about the issues that the ALP will need to consider if
it fails to win the coming federal election.
As I interpreted it, the main issues mentioned were:
- How the federal leader of the ALP should be elected;
- Corruption;
- Whether party leadership matters more than party rules;
- The ALP’s relationship with the unions;
- Politicians’ desire for personal profit;
- Personal / sexual relationships amongst participants;
- Chris Bowen’s book (Hearts and Minds) on the future of the ALP – which
see this in terms of neo-liberalism with a bit of state intervention as an
alternative to socialism. This abandons any moral criticism of capitalism or
attempt to promote social solidarity;
- Kim Carr’s Letter to Generation Next – which is from the heart. It
reflects a more optimistic left tradition and is: more keen on state
intervention; more inclined to celebrate collectivism; and more inclined to
pursue ideological distinctions. He believes in growth and markets – and argues
that strong state intervention is needed to make markets work. He strongly
supports manufacturing;
- Proposals from within British Labour Party (The Socialist Way) are more
sophisticated than those in Australia – because there are stronger left-leaning
think-tanks in UK. There is a shift towards reconsidering political economy,
rather than then mere concern with redistribution (because of problems created
by banks, and declining support for welfare state). Australian Labor looks more
to the past than the future. Britain confronts more directly rising inequality,
the effects of the GFC and government spending cuts. Some oppose statist /
centralized solutions in favour of localism / volunteerism, while others defend
traditional social democracy with reformed central state. Centralization under
Blair was seen to be counter-productive.
- Carr’s book is closest to ideas emerging from Britain – but in Australia there
is much greater faith in the power of the state to do good, and much less
interest in local / voluntary solutions
I should like to agree with your suggestion that there is a need, in seeking
future directions, to take a bigger picture view of the challenges facing the
ALP - rather than one concerned primarily with internal reforms.
My reasons for suggesting this are that: (a) the world is changing in ways that
make traditional policy prescriptions a much less relevant guide to useful
future policies; and (b) the problems that the ALP has experienced are shared
with other Australian political factions as a consequence of the need to reform
/ adapt the governmental institutions established to deal with the past to cope
in a changing environment.
The point about a changing environment can be illustrated by:
The point about governmental institutions can be illustrated by
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+). The
latter refers, for example, to:
- the increased complexity (interconnection) of policy issues which
often makes simple explanations impossible;
- inadequacies in the support available to the political system in
dealing with complex issues related to: (a) weakness that have historical roots
in the civil institutions needed to promote realistic public understanding; and
(b) politicisation of public services;
- the rise of populism (see also
On Populism, 2007+);
- Institutional changes that should help to reduce these systemic
problems.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
The Need for 'Running Repairs to the Ship of State' |
The Need for 'Running Repairs to the Ship of State' - email sent 16/11/13
Dennis Shannahan
The Australian
Re:
How Julia Gillard's ambition destroyed Kevin Rudd and ALP, The Australian,
16/11/13
Your article suggested that it was Julie Gillard’s failure
to help when Kevin Rudd was in trouble in 2010 that led to the ‘destruction of
the Labor government’ – because her actions led to the publicly unexplained
removal from office of a popular first-term Prime Minister.
However I submit that (while personalities and ambitions
play a role in politics) your explanation is too superficial, because weaknesses
in Australia’s political / governmental systems have developed and not been
remedied. These seem far more important in explaining why ‘popularity’ can be
associated with ‘dysfunction’. Machinations within the ALP were only part of the
problem (eg see
Navel Gazing Certainly Can't Solve the ALP's Problems). The latter referred
to an undoubtedly-improvable speculation about problems in Australia’s
institutions (Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building , 2003+) which, amongst
other things, referred to:
- the increased complexity (interconnection) of policy
issues which often makes simple explanations impossible;
- inadequacies in the support available to the political
system in dealing with complex issues related to: (a) weakness that have
historical roots in the civil institutions needed to promote realistic public
understanding; and (b) politicisation of public services;
- the financial imbalances in Australia’s federal system
that generate huge problems and inefficiencies in most major public sector
functions; and
- the rise of populism because of the complexity of the
issues and the lack of adequate ‘reality checks’ on popular policies by
politicised public services (see also
On Populism, 2007+).
‘Populism’ (ie the fact that a prime minister such as Mr
Rudd can be ‘popular’ though (as your article noted) it was obvious very early
on that his government was dysfunctional) is the problem that needs attention.
That problem had been obvious in 2007 (see
Sorry to Spoil the Party - but Populism Trumps Electoral Victory, 2007). And
it became increasingly obvious as the Rudd Government’s notable ‘achievement’
revealed more idealism than realism and seemed to reflect
a desire to gain applause rather than to achieve practical outcomes
(see examples in Appendix below).
By July 2010 many observers were starting
to realize that the federal government’s behaviour implied the existence of
systemic problems in Australia’s machinery of government. However merely
replacing Mr Rudd as prime minister was insufficient, as this merely addressed a
symptom rather than the cause of those problems (see
Recognizing a Need for Nation Building).
Likewise replacing ALP Governments with a
Coalition Government cannot overcome structural weakness in Australia’s
political and governmental institutions (see
Australia's Next Successful Prime Minister, 2012 and
Get Ready for Coalition Chaos,
2013). The problem is not just
limited to political personalities. And to date the Abbott
Government has shown no more sign of recognizing this than its predecessors.
Some suggestions about the sorts of
‘running repairs to the ship of state’ that might overcome the problem of
‘popular’ governments being dysfunctional are in
A Nation Building Agenda.
John Craig
Appendix: Some Examples of the Rudd
Government’s Populist Un-realism
Many of the major initiatives that have
been seen as the ‘progress’ achieved under the Rudd Government (eg as
outlined briefly in Parliamentary
MPs deliver tributes to Kevin Rudd on the news of his resignation, 13/11/13)
seem suspect. For example:
- dismantling the Howard Government’s ‘Pacific Solution’ for dealing
with asylum seekers now seems to be generally accepted to have been a mistake.
Moreover neither encouraging nor discouraging people smugglers really gets to
grips with the humanitarian disaster represented by the world’s umpteen million
refugees (see
Boat People Magic, 2013);
- saying ‘sorry’ to the stolen generations was also a feel-good,
rather than a productive, response to the difficulties facing Australians with
indigenous ancestry (see
Apology Magic?, 2008);
- establishing an Emissions Trading Scheme was another ‘feel good’
but relatively ineffectual measure – because:
- the then ‘Carbon Pollution Reduction Scheme’ only applied to CO2
which is
apparently only responsible for about half the greenhouse gas effect of
concern to the IPCC; and
- far more could have been achieved by sponsoring long-overdue
evaluation of non-anthropogenic theories of climate change to show either the
vital necessity for, or the irrelevance of, measures to contain greenhouse gas
emissions (see
Finding the Truth on Climate Change). Seriously examining all hypotheses
(not just those the IPCC long focused on) would provide the best way to reduce
‘tis – tisn’t’ political debates about the issue;
- the economic stimulus package in response to the initial effects
of the GFC (while probably good in theory) was of limited practical significance
because:
- the commodity boom that saved Australia (virtually alone amongst
OECD economies) from most of the GFC’s impacts: (a) was mainly due to China’s
unsustainable massive-investment-based response to the risks it faced; and (b)
left Australia’s economy (and government revenues) highly dependent on the
continuation of that boom; and
- more fundamental questions about Australia’s long term economic
strategy were not addressed (eg see
Lifting Productivity: Considering the Bigger Picture, 2010);
- rolling out a National Broadband Network through a government
owned company was always likely to limit scope for discovering better options
and lower costs (NBN's
Bigger Picture , 2010);
- the health and hospital reform plan seemed anything but
constructive (see
Is a National Health and Hospitals Network Progress?, 2010) because:
- it focused on boosting medical services – though more could
arguably be achieved by addressing the environmental and nutritional quality
issues that are giving rise to the escalation of the chronic degenerate diseases
that consume much of health budgets; and
- the plan simply reinforced the limitations on effective /
efficient service delivery that are implicit in Australia’s world-beating
federal financial imbalances;
- the Resource Super Profits Tax seemed unlikely to be a significant
source of the revenue needed to compensate for Australia’s growing structural
budget deficits – see
RSPT Won't Hurt Miners: But Pity Help Naive Australians.
Other indications of the lack of pragmatic realism in the
idealistic reforms sought by the Rudd Government include:
- Infrastructure Magic? (January 2008) – which suggests that setting up an
organization (eg Infrastructure Australia) whose name implies that is the
‘solution’ to a difficult policy problem is a classic, but ineffectual, way of
addressing such problems;
- Talkfest Magic? (February 2008) – which suggests that a one-off summit is
unlikely to be able to come up with much in the way of practical / achievable
policy options;
- Productivity Magic? (April 2008) – which argues that developing the private
sector’s capabilities will contribute more to productivity than improving
government functions that are often subjected to serious market failures;
- Public Service Magic? (May 2008) – which suggests Public Service
professionalism is unlikely to be restored if politicisation (ie installing
cronies and ‘yes men’) remains the preferred method for achieving this.
|
Undermining Australia's System of Government from the Top? |
Undermining Australia's System of Government from the Top? - email sent 23/11/13
Sarah Elks
The Australian
Re:
Monarchists not happy as Quentin backs republic, gay marriage, The
Australian, 23-24/11/13
Your article pointed to yet another irresponsible Governor
General politicising that position in apparent ignorance of the implications
this has for Australia’s system of government.
This problem was explored further some years ago in
Politicization of the ‘Crown’ (2003+), which suggested that:
- Existing constitutional arrangements depend on the head of state
(eg Governor General) holding essentially all executive power and using it only
on the advice of an elected Government that has the confidence of the lower
house of Parliament (while keeping an eye on whether the said Government is
playing by the rules / constitution in the things that it asks the Governor
General to endorse);
- If the head of state has an independent political agenda (as the
current holder of the position apparently aspires to have), their willingness /
ability to carry out that role must be suspect, and there is a real risk of
either:
- Instabilities associated with conflicts between the elected
Government and the head of state; or
- Abuses of power associated with collaboration between them in the
absence of any apolitical oversight, if their political agendas are aligned;
- Australia could becoming a republic relatively simply providing
the (say) President can be assured of being apolitical;
- Extensive revisions of Australia’s constitution would be required
to achieve stability / effective government if a President had a political
agenda that was independent of the elected Government (eg if a President were
directly elected). Something like the American system (eg where the Executive is
an elected president and their power is counterbalanced by a legislature that is
separate from the Executive) might be needed. Such revisions would be difficult
to get through (noting the low success rate of referenda generally). Those who
advocate an Australian republic (eg the present Governor General) do not seem to
have yet thought through this aspect of the issue.
John Craig
|
The Choice Between Evils that Governments Now Face: 'Process
Addiction' or Bad Decisions |
The Choice Between Evils that Governments Now Face: 'Process Addiction' or Bad Decisions - email sent 10/12/13
Editor
The Australian
Re:
Reviews mount as Abbott cabinet must direct action,
editorial, and Kelly J. ‘Too
many reviews expose Abbott to ‘process addiction’,
The Australian, 9/12/13
It is
interesting, but hardly surprising, that the Abbott Government now apparently
finds itself embroiled in commissioning umpteen inquiries rather than acting
decisively.
This is
however an inevitable consequence of the complexity of the issues that
governments face and the weaknesses of Australia’s institutional support to the
political system (ie of the lack of civil institutions able to take an
up-to-date and realistic approach to policy issues, and of the
decay
that public services have suffered
as a result of a desire to make them more ‘responsive’ to political agendas
and more ‘business-like’ (ie competitive rather than
collaborative) in undertaking their
primarily-non-business-like functions).
What
seems to be happening to the Abbott Government was fairly predictable (eg see
Get
Ready for Coalition Chaos).
This is quite like what happened to Queensland’s unfortunate Borbidge Government
in the 1990s. It came to power on the basis of the lack of practical
achievements of the Goss Government which had preceded it, and then found that
it needed about 90 inquiries before it would be in a position to make reliable
decisions. Those inquiries were all reporting at about the time that the
Borbidge Government was voted out because of its inactivity. It was then
replaced by the Beattie administration, which apparently decided that it had to
‘just do things’ even though it was not certain about what to do. The result was
even worse than the Borbidge Government’s inactivity – ie publicly-visible
crises in many government functions and an unsustainable blow-out in government
debts.
The
Abbott Government has an unfortunate choice between two evils (ie making
often-bad decisions or manifest indecisiveness / inactivity while conducting a
large number of inquiries).
This
problem (ie the complexity of policy issues that renders
simplistic decisiveness hazardous) can be illustrated by Mr Abbott’s desire to be an ‘infrastructure prime
minister’ and to give priority to the development of roads. The problem is that:
- A
primary emphasis on roads is arguably not desirable in providing for much of
Australia’s future transport needs – for reasons suggested in
Brisbane’s Transport Monster.
The latter notes: (a) constraints (ie high fuel costs) associated with ‘peak oil’ that fracking
technologies have arguably not eliminated; (b) the apparent peaking some years
ago of urban motor vehicle usage – in terms of vehicle kilometers travelled; and
(c) the adoption of ‘urban footprints’ in major cities for environmental reasons
that block access to the cheap rights of way that are needed for affordable
freeway systems;
- Any
decisions about transport systems need to be closely integrated with land use
and many other considerations, and funding of random roads through a federal
government agency which is not able to coordinate with those other
considerations is unlikely to be beneficial.
This
is not the only area in which the
policy agenda on which the Coalition Government won power in 2013 seems to need
significant reviews before sensible actions could be committed. For example::
- Financial, economic and security difficulties in the international environment
(eg those associated with 'Asia' and global debt constraints) are likely to
adversely affect Australia but don’t seem to have been adequately considered in
developing policy proposals. Thus domestic economic and fiscal challenges are
likely to be different from / harder than those that have been presumed, and
effective international relationships will be a struggle;
- Diversification from economic reliance on mining is needed, but can’t be
achieved by just ‘more or the same’ economic reforms;
- Assumptions about what is needed for effective government seem naïve. For
example: (a)
difficulties in ‘governing’ generally are likely if fiscal challenges are
addressed in isolation
(ie through a Commission of Audit); and (b) Deficiencies in the provision of
public goods and services for which the Commonwealth has no constitutional power
can’t be overcome by ever-more-intrusive attempts to micro-manage state
activities.
Unless and until there is a serious effort to develop more effective
institutional support to Australia’s political system (eg as suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building
, 2003+), all future governments will presumably face the same ‘choice between
evils’ that now confronts the Abbott Government.
John Craig
|
Rebuilding Australia's System of Government |
Rebuilding Australia's System of Government - email sent 4/1/14
Klaas Woldring
Re:
System reconstruction in Australia is long overdue, Online Opinion,
3/1/14
Your article suggested that, because of problems with
Australia’s system of government, it would be best to adopt a ‘non-Westminster’
political system (such as that in Scandinavia, Holland, Germany and Austria) –
ie a system characterised by a search for cooperation amongst a number of
parties rather than the ‘adversarialism of the Westminster system’.
There is no doubt about the need for reform of Australia’s
system of government. The struggle that the present federal government is
experiencing parallels that of its predecessors and was quite predictable (eg
see
Get Ready for Coalition Chaos, June 2013).
However there is a fundamental difference between the Roman
Law traditions on which the ‘European’ systems that you suggest as a future
option for Australia and the British Law tradition that underpins the
Westminister system. The former regards the state as having legal priority over
individuals, whereas the latter gives much greater emphasis to the legal status
and capabilities of individuals. These differences have deep cultural roots and
arguably have been the cause of many conflicts in recent centuries (see
Fragmentation of the Global Order, 2001).
Thus I respectfully suggest that any proposals for reform
of Australia’s political system on ‘European’ lines needs to fully consider the
issues involved. For example, giving legal priority to the state increases the
risk of authoritarianism. And a requirement for political consensus before
governments can form can increase the risk of indecisiveness – and thus of being
slow to learn from making mistakes.
There are arguably ways to rebuild Australia’s system of
government that would be compatible with the Westminster tradition that has been
the foundation of that system in the past – eg as suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+).
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Beyond Infrastructure Despair |
Beyond Infrastructure Despair - email sent 27/1/14
Michael Deegan
Infrastructure Australia
Re: Hepworth A.,
Roads to despair: we're 'living beyond our need', The Australian,
27/1/14
You were quoted as pointing out that
Australia has significant infrastructure problems – especially in relation to
roads.
My interpretation of the article in which
you are quoted: Australia is now
living beyond its ‘needs’. Road revenues exceed road spending. Some roads are in
disrepair, some little used and others congested. Simply providing more money
won’t solve this problem. In a study of infrastructure by Infrastructure
Australia roads were the only infrastructure type to fail every test. The Prime
Minister has said that he wants to be an infrastructure prime minister.
Infrastructure minister (Warren Truss) has asked state and territory officials
to identify projects in national land transport network. Road agencies are
dealing with infrastructure that is not fit for its purpose and governments face
expectations for roads that they can’t meet. While the private sector was
willing to invest it was never given the right to make freight-focused
investments when they make commercial sense
I should like to submit for your
consideration that Australia’s infrastructure problems are not limited to roads,
and require systemic solutions (rather than continued efforts to identify lists
of ‘project’ for federal governments to try to get political applause by
announcing). A now somewhat dated attempt to identify critical systemic
obstacles to infrastructure development was outlined in
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy (2005).
Unfortunately the latter is probably still relevant because changes since then
have tended to simply be more of what has long been making infrastructure
development so complex, expensive and ineffective.
Systemic problems have included:
- Federal fiscal imbalances which have made it all but impossible
for states to take serious responsibility for their nominal (eg infrastructure)
functions – and have left them with no financial incentives to take economic
development (and thus the creation of a strong tax base) seriously. For reasons
suggested in
Federal-state fiscal Imbalances consequences in relation to the provision of
public goods and services have included: irresponsibility, buck passing,
duplication and complexity, and 'pork barrelling'. Government functions have
been rendered wasteful and ineffectual. The effect has been rather like the
effect of tariff protection on manufacturing (ie encouraging others to focus on
lobbying for federal funding rather than on whatever job really needs to be
done);
- Fragmentation of responsibility within government administrations
as a consequence of seeking to make service delivery more ‘business-like’
(ie competitive rather than collaborative) in the
performance of essentially non-business-like functions;
- Encouragement of direct private sector control / financing of
public goods and services that are subjected to very real market failures; and
- Politicisation of public services to avoid any reality check on
the implantation of populist (ie ‘Yes Minister’ influenced) policies.
Getting beyond despair about Australia’s infrastructure
functions is possible. But it requires change.
Might I respectfully suggest that Infrastructure Australia
could make a major difference by addressing such systemic obstacles? Australia
needs a federal government committed to ‘governing’ (ie making it possible for
others to ‘do things’) rather than one that tries to micro-manage everything.
Centralised decisions about an economy tend to be just
plain silly. The same clearly applies in relation to infrastructure – as
suggested in relation to the present federal government’s ambitions to spend
heavily on roads (see
The Choice Between Evils that Governments Now Face: 'Process Addiction' or Bad
Decisions).
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
And the Winner of the 2014 'Pink Batts' Award is ....
|
And the Winner of the 2014 'Pink Batts' Award is .... - email sent 15/5/14
Ian McAuley
University of Canberra
Re:
Rudd humbled, but real lessons of insulation scheme go unlearned, The
Conversation, 15/5/14
Your article suggested that the inquiry
into the Home Insulation Program (the formal name of the Rudd
Government’s notorious $2.5bn
‘pink batts’ response to the global financial crisis) has
focused on “who knew what, and when (and that this was) entertaining political
theatre, but not a productive use of public resources”. You also pointed out
that “the commission’s hearings confirms the findings of the 2010
Auditor-General’s report into the Home Insulation Program, which found that
many of the problems resulted from systemic failures in public administration.”
I would like to submit for your consideration that a new
Award could be given in future along with other national honours – namely a
‘Pink Batts’ Award. The Home Insulation Program is not unique. Governments have
implemented many superficially attractive initiatives in recent years which
turned out in practice to be either ineffectual or counter-productive (eg see
On Populism, 2007).
The ‘Pink Batts’ Award could be given for the government
initiative that superficially sounded the most plausible but contained the seeds
of severe problems that experienced / careful consideration would have revealed.
I should like to also suggest that the recent federal
budget included several candidates for a future ‘Pink Batts’ Award.
Three
contenders are mentioned on my web-site. In brief it is suggested that:
- The proposed large increase in conventional defence spending
should be considered for an Award because it is likely that boosting Australia’s
security now mainly requires more emphasis on ‘soft power’ capacity;
- The proposed large increase in spending on infrastructure
(especially roads) might justify an Award because: (a) the imbalances between
the taxing capacity and spending responsibilities of the federal and state
governments have long been a source of duplication, uncertainty, buck-passing
and wastage; and (b) the emphasis which the federal government wants to give on road
infrastructure seems inconsistent with current real-world infrastructure
priorities and illustrates why the use of the power of the purse by federal
governments to control the public goods and services that states provide is
dysfunctional;
- The proposed large increase in medical research funding may
deserve an Award because boosting Australia’s economy through enhancing
innovation primarily depends on creating the competencies and organisation to
commercialize potentially valuable ideas. There is little to be gained simply
continuing to: (a) provide ever more ‘smart’ inputs (eg research and education)
to an economy that remains insufficiently developed to use them productively;
and (b) block the development of the economies’ innovation capacity through
internal government programs to ‘assist’ potential innovators.
The existence of systemic problems that can give rise to
candidates for ‘Pink Batts’ Awards has been apparent for some years (see
Challenges to Australia’s Democratic Institutions, 2003+). These systemic
problems were on the point of gaining recognition in 2010 when the ALP
leadership concluded that the Rudd Government had ‘lost its way’ (see
Starting to Acknowledge Ineffectual Government).
However Australia’s system of government still needs
repair, as the present Federal Government also seems to be ‘flying by the seat of its
pants’. Perhaps Luke 23:34 is relevant.
John Craig
Three Candidates
A ‘Pink Batts’ Award for National Security?
The 2014 budget included a proposal to increase ‘defence’ spending to 2% of
GDP. The problem with this is that this will be focused on increasing
conventional ‘hard power’ defence capabilities, when Australia’s security
challenges increasingly require mainly ‘soft power’ responses [or at least they
have done for several past years].
The world is now afflicted by serious geo-political
instabilities (see
Geopolitical Indicators).
For example, the Muslim world seems to be plagued by
conflicts as attempts are made to decide which (if any) system of political
economy would best enable such societies to overcome the constraints that have
kept them mired in backwardness for centuries. So far the chaos in the Muslim
world has affected Australia through the flows of asylum seekers that conflicts
have generated. But there could be much worse consequences in future. These
could be headed off by helping afflicted countries to find systems of political
economy that would be likely to work – and this requires ‘soft power’ strengths
more than traditional ‘hard power’ (eg see
Boat People Magic).
Likewise Australia faces security challenges from East Asia
that are most likely to involve the use of ‘soft power’. Traditional East Asian
Art of War tactics feature deception and encouraging opponents to make
mistakes which weaken their position. To counter such tactics Australia needs,
for example, to strengthen government institutions so that ‘pink batts’ programs
don’t continue to emerge. Conventional ‘hard power’ resources are not sufficient
to counter East Asian Art of War tactics (see
Comments on Australia's Strategic Edge in 2030 ).
The federal budget’s proposal for a large increase in
conventional military spending is a real contender for the 2014 ‘Pink Batts’
Award.
A ‘Pink Batts’ Award for Public Goods and Services?
There are major problems in Australia’s federal system.
The Federal Government has control of most revenue. And the
states have only limited and at-times unsatisfactory sources of revenue – even
though they have are responsible for providing most public goods and services
(eg in areas such as infrastructure, hospitals and schools). The imbalances in
Australia’s federal financial arrangements have long produced duplication,
uncertainty, buck-passing and wastage (see
Federal Fiscal Imbalances).
The 2014 federal budget will force federal-state
negotiations about hospital and school funding, because it has cut federal
payments for these services and thereby perhaps encouraged state press for
increases in the GST. However this has gone nowhere near what is needed for
states to be able to take real responsibility for, and competently plan and
provide, public goods and services. How more fundamental reform might be
achieved was speculated in
Fixing Australia’s Federation. The latter referred, for example, to
dramatically reducing the need for the federal government to play any role in
funding state functions and seeking alternative methods to promote coordination.
The 2014 budget has demonstrated why fundamental reform is
needed. Infrastructure takes many forms and all need to be planned and developed
in close collaboration with the organisations responsible for other functions.
Approval of funding of isolated ‘projects’ by the federal government does not
allow effective and efficient infrastructure planning and development (eg see
Infrastructure: A Big Picture View). In fact it has precisely the reverse
effect. This is well illustrated by the budget’s commitment to an increase in
infrastructure funding with a major emphasis on roads. This emphasis on roads is
out of touch with the fact (illustrated in
Brisbane’s Transport Monster) that:
- Rising fuel costs have reportedly resulted in a peaking some years
ago of urban motor vehicle usage (in terms of vehicle kilometres travelled) and
though ‘fracking’ technologies have reduced the constraints on liquid fuel
production that the peaking of conventional oil production implied, they have
not reduced the constraints on vehicle usage implicit by rising fuel costs;
- There has been a shift in urban infrastructure priorities towards
public transport. Australia’s major cities have adopted ‘urban footprints’ to
inhibit the adverse environmental effects of urban sprawl. This has not only
blocked access to the cheap rights-of-way that are needed for inexpensive
freeways, it has also been complemented by a change in urban forms to emphasize
higher densities and public transport .
While a federal agency such as Infrastructure Australia
(for example) can make a list of possible projects, it is in no position to
ensure that any particular project is well integrated with other aspects of its
regional environment. And Australia’s private infrastructure lobbies (who will
presumably favour road infrastructure because it can conveniently be privately
provided) are also not in a position to balance infrastructure decisions with
other regional factors.
The federal budget’s proposal to focus a large increase on
infrastructure spending on roads is thus also a real contender for the 2014
‘Pink Batts’ Award.
A ‘Pink Batts’ Award for Research?
The 2014 budget included a proposal large long-term
increase in funding for medical research – apparently partly because this is
seen as a way of boosting Australia’s capacity to innovate and invent (Parnell
S., $20bn medical ‘future fund’ eases the pain, The Australian, 14/5/14).
While medical research in itself is undoubtedly a ‘good’
thing and this is an area in which Australia has leading edge research
competencies, it is not certain that this should be a high priority in terms of
benefiting Australia’s economy at the expense of other areas of research or
other uses for those funds.
Australia now has a significant economic challenge. It has
been recognised since the 1980s that boosting the economy’s capacity in
innovation is a path to achieving international competitiveness in high
productivity / high wage industries. However the big gap in Australia’s ability
to innovate has never been in any lack of bright and potentially valuable ideas.
Rather it has been in economic underdevelopment (ie in the lack of the
commercial competencies and organisation within the market economy to turn
‘smart inputs’ (such as research) into commercially / economically significant
opportunities into successful enterprises – see
Political Push on Economic Inputs Can Achieve Little
Progress has been limited because governments: (a) have
given in to interest group pressure to fund ‘smart inputs’ (ie education and
research) though the economy has remained insufficiently developed to properly
exploit them (eg see
The Futility of 'Backing Australia's Ability 2'); and (b) sought to provide
‘assistance’ to potentially innovators rather than stimulating the
market-responsive economy to develop the capacity to do so (see
Problems with Direct Government 'Assistance').
Irrespective of what health benefits the world would get
from a large program of medical research in Australia, Australia won’t get
significant economic benefits unless a serious attempt is made to develop the
expertise and organisation within the market economy to achieve
commercially-successful innovations on a large scale (eg as suggested in
A Case for Innovative Economic Leadership, 2009). In such an environment
government investment in basic research will have an important part to play. But
medical research would not necessarily be the area of highest priority.
The federal budget’s proposal for a large increase in
funding for medical research is thus also a real contender for the 2014 ‘Pink
Batts’ Award.
|
A
Bigger Picture View of Australia's Challenges |
A Bigger Picture View of Australia's Challenges - email sent 27/5/14
Rob Burgess
Business Spectator
Re:
Weak logic beneath Australia’s biggest gamble, Business Spectator,
27/5/14
I should like to try to add value to your
article’s suggestion that a more holistic view of Australia’s challenges is
needed than is reflected in the recent federal budget (which was limited to
financial considerations) – because the latter involves overly simplistic
assumptions about what is required for Australia is to become more
internationally competitive. Your article also noted that:
- Many factors have been critical to Australia’s
past strengths and success (such as human capital, legal and political
institutions and traditions, international relationships, ‘brand Australia’ and
a strong work ethic);
- Unless such issues are considered, radical reform
(such as the federal budget attempted) can cause inadvertent damage; and
- The federal budget could put Australia’s “world
beating stock of human capital on the line for uncertain gain”.
There is little doubt about the need to
take the broader view (eg about the position of Australia’s human capital) that
your article suggested. Some reasons for a broader approach than was reflected
in the federal budget were mentioned in
Restoring The Viability of Democratic Capitalism. The latter referred, for
example, to: the inability of current government machinery to deal with
increasingly complex issues; the unfamiliar cultures and practices that now need
to be taken into account; the inadequate support to the democratic process from
dependent civil institutions and politicised public services; the need to
accelerate economic development; the problems associated with federal financial
imbalances; and the need to cease assuming that business-like methods help in
undertaking governments’ non-business-like functions.
Moreover:
John Craig
|
Political Malfunction in Australia: A Way Forward |
Political Malfunction in Australia: A Way Forward - email sent 5/7/14
The Editor
The Australian
Re:
Our politics is in crisis, the community deep in denial, The Australian,
5/7/14
Your editorial suggested that all is not well with
Australia’s political system and that this is likely to have adverse
consequences for Australian’s future welfare. However it is not just the general
community that is in denial about Australia’s challenges. The same arguably
applies to community leaders. A breakthrough is needed.
My
interpretation of your editorial: The
Australian has long campaigned for reforms
in Australia to make it freer, smarter, richer and more democratic. But
Australia’s political system is now in malfunction. The nation is in denial
about its economic challenges – and political decision making is ineffective.
There is a culture of complaint, a decline in self-reliance, a belief that all
problems are governments’ fault, political searches for votes by claiming that
government can solve all problems, and a media that mirrors this narcissism and
short-termism. Politics is noisy, destructive and consumed with self-interest
without a capacity for collective self-improvement. The government faces huge
challenges – especially with a hostile senate packed with political beginners.
After two decades of uninterrupted growth, Australia has a political / social
culture that is complacent and feels ‘entitled’. Expectations exceed what can be
financed by taxes on a business-as-usual basis. It has depended on economic
reforms that started in 1983 and a fading China boom. There are many external
risks and financial markets are distorted. There is a need to control the budget
to reduce Australia’s risks. There is no agreement about the need to do this,
and proposals for budgetary reform have been mired in concerns about fairness.
Doing nothing would consign Australia to a miserable, low-growth future and a
high level of exposure to external economic shocks.
The risks to Australians’ welfare that your editorial
pointed to are valid – though probably understated for reasons suggested in
Restoring The Viability of Democratic Capitalism (2014) and
The Challenge and Potential Cost of Inequality and Insufficient Income
(2014). There is moreover a need to consider the political malfunctions that
your editorial referred to in a broader context
Just as Australia’s need for economic reform started to be
recognised in the 1970s and received attention a decade or so later, so there is
now a need to address defects in Australia’s system of government that started
to become obvious in the 1990s (eg those suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+).
Many factors have contributed to Australia’s current
political malaise. The biggest ‘denial’ challenge is that the economic and
public sector ‘reform’ that community leaders have supported in recent decades
has been inadequate and has had dysfunctional unintended consequences. To
overcome this, Australia’s civil institutions, which have had the dominant
influence on political thinking, arguably need to devote more effort to
understanding (for example):
- the nature and functions of government. This does not seem to have
been well understood perhaps because Australia’s system of government was
inherited, rather than developed locally. Because of this ‘reforms’ that were
hoped to be beneficial have sometimes compounded existing weaknesses (see
Decay of Australian Public Administration, 2002 and
Neglected Side Effects, 2004). Governments’ core function is ‘governing’
(see
Governing is not just Running a Large Business) yet political leaders were
enticed into micro-management, eg by heeding advice to emphasise a business-like
approach to service delivery, or by demand for ‘national’
(ie generous-government-funded) action. Likewise to
speed reform, ‘Yes Minister’ thinking led to politicisation of public services
to promote ‘responsiveness’ to new political agendas (rather than building on
existing knowledge and experience of the complex functions of government).
Elected governments thus tended to surround themselves with ‘yes men’; to
deprive themselves of sufficient experience-based ‘reality checks’ of
superficially-plausible policies (see
On Populism, 2007+); and to make it very difficult for
governments to realize that not everyone understood or supported their
policies (eg see
The Origin and Spread of the 'Queensland Effect',
2001);
- the requirements and options for building economic
competitiveness. The need for economic reform has been widely recognised since
the 1970s, and was addressed in the 1980s and 1990s. However the
market-liberalization emphasis of the economic reform agenda (whose main impact
was to expose individuals and enterprises to competition) was not on its own an
adequate basis for ongoing economic competitiveness (see
Defects in Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes, 2000 and
Lifting Productivity: Considering the Bigger Picture, 2009);
- the implications of changes in Australia’s international
environment (eg see
Babes in the Asian Woods, 2009+ and
An Approaching Crisis?, 2013+).
To break through the very real problems outlined in your
editorial arguably requires something like the solution to a similar political
malaise (ie so-called
Eurosclerosis) that affected Europe in the 1970s. Civil institutions
outside the political system ended the political impasse (through the so-called
Europe 1992 process) by putting in place new real-world arrangements which
meant that political change was clearly not just a zero-sum game (ie a question
of ‘fairness’). One of hopefully-many options to create a positive-sum game out
of the reforms needed to boost Australia’s future productivity and
competitiveness is suggested in
A Case for Innovative Economic Leadership (2009). Options for
behind-the-scenes changes to strengthen Australia’s civil and state institutions
more generally were outlined in
A Nation Building Agenda (2010).
John Craig
|
Sorting Out Australia's Infrastructure Mess Needs 'Government' not
Micro-management |
Sorting Out Australia's Infrastructure Mess Needs 'Government' not Micro-management - email sent 18/7/14
Callam Pickering
Re:
Abbott's infrastructure projects must have a solid foundation, Business
Spectator, 18/7/14
Your article points to the need to avoid
the scatter-gun approach to infrastructure project selection that has led to bad
decisions in recent years. One cause of the problem undoubtedly lies in federal
government efforts to micro-manage state functions as a consequence of: (a) the
mal-distribution of taxing power and revenues in Australia’s federation; and (b)
an unrealistic faith in central planning. Practical solutions are not hard to
find – but would require the federal ‘government’ to actually get on with its
job (ie ‘governing’ – rather than just seeking to ‘do things’ itself).
My interpretation of your article:
The federal government deserves credit
for emphasizing the importance of infrastructure. A report from Productivity
Commission reminds us of the importance of project choice (rather than spending
more of just privatizing state assets). It advocated a comprehensive overhaul of
planning processes. Australia has had an infrastructure shortfall for decades.
Infrastructure will be emphasised by the G20 and the federal treasurer has noted
federal government’s goal of being the infrastructure government. The
Productivity noted the need for caution about project selection and
privatisation. Well targeted infrastructure spending is vital for Australia’s
future. The federal government needs to make sure that it gets the projects
right.
The problem with the conclusion in your
article is that it is virtually impossible for any federal government agency to
identify the ‘right’ projects for many types of infrastructure (eg because of
the need to integrate such decisions with other aspects of the functions of
which infrastructure is the capital component, or with the requirements of other
government functions or with the requirements of regional development
generally).
Because of this the federal government’s
announced major emphasis on road infrastructure spending arguably qualifies as a
solid contender for a 2014 ‘pink batts’ award (see
Public Goods and Services in
And the Winner of the 2014 'Pink Batts' Award is ..... ). The latter
includes suggestions about how the problem might be resolved. Unfortunately this
requires that federal governments moderate their search for political applause
by deciding which projects have the most solid foundations, and rather get on
with ‘governing’ instead (ie creating a framework within which others can make
such judgments without having to rely on financial handouts to implement them).
The imbalances that exist in Australia’s federal financial
arrangements have had many adverse consequences (see
Federal State Fiscal Imbalances, 2003+). This is however not solely to blame
for the disaster that Australia’s processes for developing infrastructure have
become. Politicisation of public services and the virtual demolition of
machinery that could competently plan and develop infrastructure (out of a
desire to make governments more efficient through adopting a business-like
approach to their non-business-like functions) are also significant
considerations (eg see
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia’s Economy, 2005 and
Infrastructure:
A Big Picture View, 2012).
John Craig
Note added later: In October 2014
it was noted that:
- the assumptions being made by Australia's federal
government about the best options for providing electricity to communities (ie
via remote coal fired power stations) were being out-dated by electrical
engineers and energy economists who were pursuing increasingly affordable,
small-scale power supply technologies such as solar photovoltaics [1].
Central planning is a hazardous business.
- a satirical TV series highlighted the effect
that political appeal, rather than economic effectiveness, would have on
project selection by a fictional 'National Building Authority' [1]
|
Deeper Analysis of Security
Issues |
Deeper Analysis of Security Issues - email sent 16/11/14
Meron Wondemaghen
University of New England
Re: Defining
deviance: four steps in constructing a threat to security, The
Conversation, 13/11/14
Your article
concerned the political process whereby a threat which requires a response is
constructed. This used the example of debates about boat people (an issue that
recently has evolved into concerns about Australians joining foreign fighters).
I should like
to suggest that at each stage in this process the public / political perceptions
involved have tended to be superficial, because there have been much deeper
issues involved.
For example,
there were very significant issues involved in the background to the arrival in
recent years of ‘boat people’ mainly from the Middle East (eg security
concerns for Australia and the inadequacy of ‘people smuggling’ as a
solution to the humanitarian disaster reflected by the world’s umpteen million
displaced persons). Yet in the first instance, debate seemed to focus on whether
racism was the primary basis on which the question was being evaluated (see
Complexities
in the Refugee Problem, 2001+). And when there was consensus on problems
associated with people smuggling, emphasis was only given to protecting
Australia from being affected – rather than on what might be done to eliminate
the problem at its source (see Boat
People Magic, 2013).
Likewise
Australia’s initial response to the ‘war against terror’ (which has
morphed into a campaign against the so-called Islamic State) was apparently
based on a very superficial analysis / understanding of the issues involved (eg
see Poor
Evaluation of Strategic Issues ,
2003). And more recent efforts to fight that ‘war’ continue to be based on
superficial assessments (eg see Politicians
are Wrong: Terrorism by Islamist Extremists Does Involve Islam).
And other
security issues are seen to be arising in Asia which again require a much more
sophisticated understanding and analysis that Australia’s institutions seem to
be capable of providing (eg see Comments
on Australia's Strategic Edge in 2030,
2011).
It is my
suspicion that Australia’s institutional support to the political process
needs to be considerably strengthened in order to overcome / reduce such
problems – for reasons developed further in Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building
(2003+)
John Craig
Further Notes Added Later
Australia’s response to ‘strategic’ issues generally
(ie those that are emerging that are likely to have a significant impact) has
often been superficial. This
seems to be a by-product of: (a) the Lucky Country syndrome – ie the fact
that Australians have believed that they will be OK no matter what; and (b)
Australia’s reliance on importing public policies from UK / US / OECD –
rather than doing the necessary serious work here. And this has worked fairly
well because Australia has genuinely been ‘lucky’ in relation to resource wealth and
benefiting from friendly liaison with the world’s most advanced nations. However
now the world is changing and the naivety of Australia's official proposals for
dealing with with a prospective 'Asian Century' illustrates the hazards of being
behind the eight ball (see Australia in the
Clayton's Century: The 'Asian' Century you have when you are not having an Asian
Century, 2012)
The present writer's basis for suggesting that responses tend to be superficial involved about 4
decades of ‘strategic’ policy R&D – ie looking at what is coming at
Queensland / Australia from the world, and at the slow / inadequate responses that seem to be
all too common (because it hasn’t really mattered).
Politics has tended to be seen as a game –
rather than a serious issue affecting people’s welfare and security. The
response to ‘boat people’ (for example) was largely a game of political point
scoring. It did not involve looking at the serious global issues of which boat
people were symptoms. And, in
recent years superficiality has arguably become much more widespread –
because public service politicisation eliminated what had been a key source
of a ‘reality check’ on mere populism (see
On
Populism, 2007+).
But now the chickens are likely
to come home to roost. Despite the rhetoric surrounding the November 2014 G20 meeting in
Brisbane, the easy days are over. The world is in trouble (see
An
Approaching Crisis). The G20 has not
solved the problem (eg see Counter-cyclical
policy can't solve structural problems ;
Sustainable
Growth Requires More than an Infrastructure 'Trick' and
Creeping
Threats to the Global Economy). Australia’s resource-boom luck has run out –
and the economy is inadequately developed to quickly create viable alternatives
(eg see How
Durable is Australia's Luck?). Community expectations are much higher
than the economy / government can sustain (see
The Challenge and Potential Cost of
Inequality and Insufficient Income). The liberty that has been the
foundations of Western societies success is highly prized, but is being
challenged with determination by societies whose traditional cultures are
incompatible with individual liberty (eg see
Is
the 'Free World' in Decline?).
Thus it is important that the way Australia responds to strategic challenges (as what to
do about ‘boat people’ was at one stage) should be evaluated in terms of whether those
responses genuinely dealt with the underlying real issues – rather than by
analyzing the way political games have been played for the entertainment of an under-informed
electorate.
|
Strengthening Australia's
Democracy
|
Strengthening Australian Democracy -
email sent 22/11/14
Hon Mr Tony Abbott, MP Prime Minister of Australia
Important international changes are impacting on
Australians.
For example, your recent email (which is reproduced
on my web-site) pointed to Australia’s prospective Free Trade Agreement (FTA)
with China. Economic and business observers clearly believe this FTA contains many attractive features
and complements other actual and prospective FTAs in Asia. The G20 meeting in
Brisbane reached agreement on many initiatives intended to boost global economic
growth. At the time of the G20 meeting China’s president spoke to
Australia’s parliament about the possibility of entering a ‘comprehensive
strategic partnership’. India’s prime minister also spoke to parliament
about the opportunity to develop closer economic and strategic ties.
I would like to suggest that it is desirable for the
government to encourage Australians to gain a deep understanding of the
strategic context in which such ‘deals’ are being considered. Australia has
an unfortunate history of forming policy on the basis of a fairly superficial
view of world events (see Deeper
Analysis of Security Issues). While benefits have traditionally come
from going along with the great powers of the day, there is a need now for more
than this. Democracy works well when the community has a sound understanding of
the issues that political leaders are grappling with. But, when significant
segments of the community don’t have a basis for such understanding, the
political process can:
The
China FTA and Possible ‘Partnership’ suggests examples of the need to
deepen public understanding of Australia’s strategic context. It
implies, for example, that it would be dangerously naïve to try to negotiate
improved relationships without access to a much better understanding than that
of the apparently-Asia-illiterate authors of the 2012 Australia in the Asian
Century White Paper (eg see Australia
in the Clayton’s Century: The ‘Asian' Century You Have When You are not
Having an Asian Century, 2012).
It is not simply up to governments to undertake research
and stimulate debates to raise the electorate’s understanding. If Australia is
genuinely to maximize its own prospects (rather than becoming a victim) and
become a significant influence in making the world a better place by developing
constructive relationships in ‘Asia’, governments also need to encourage /
stimulate Australia’s civil society as a whole to improve its game in this
regard (eg see A
Nation Building Agenda).
John Craig
The
China FTA and Possible ‘Partnership’: Illustrating the Need for Deeper
Public Understanding of Australia’s Strategic Context [Working Draft]
The Economic Benefits
A recent email from Australia’s Prime Minister (Tony
Abbott) drew attention to the benefits Australians would gain from a proposed Free
Trade Agreement (FTA) with China.
From: Tony Abbott [mailto:.....] On Behalf Of Tony Abbott
Sent: Monday, 17 November 2014 7:54 PM
Subject:
Delivering real benefits for Australians
Australia has just concluded a
historic free trade agreement with the world’s second largest economy, China.
This agreement, with our largest trading partner, will add billions to our
economy, create jobs and drive higher living standards for Australians. Freer
trade, means more jobs and a stronger economy – it’s that simple. This
is good news for Australia – because it will mean more investment and more
jobs. It's also good for consumers, because when trade barriers fall, prices
fall with them. Families will benefit from lower prices for essential
family goods. This agreement greatly improves Australia’s competitive
position, providing significant benefits to Australian farmers – particularly
for producers of dairy, beef, sheep meat, wine, seafood, grains and
horticulture. Australia’s services industries such as legal services,
education, telecommunications, tourism and travel, construction and engineering,
and health and aged care services will all benefit from being able to do
business in China more easily. Along with agreements signed with Korea and Japan
earlier this year, this agreement with China forms part of a powerful trifecta
of agreements with our major trading partners in North Asia. These economies
account for more than 60 per cent of our exports of goods. These agreements
are a major part of the Government’s Economic Action Strategy to build a
strong and prosperous economy and a safe and secure Australia. Find out
more about the agreement
here.
Businesses generally seem to see the FTA to: (a) have major
potential economic benefits;
and (b) be only the first step towards a broader 'partnership' with China.
Signing the FTA with China was worth the 10 year wait. The agreement is
transformational. It puts many important Australian industries on more
competitive international footing. It will improve: trade; job creation;
and business confidence. NZ gained a lot from a similar agreement.
China's growing middle class is a major factor. The business community
needs to build on the FTA and encourage deeper collaboration. There is a
need to think creatively about the benefits of Chinese investment.
China's continuing economic reform is welcomed (eg in relation to
exchange rates and foreign investment) though more needs to be done. The
renminbi is likely to dominate Asian trade and perhaps challenge the $US
as global reserve currency. Thus China's confirmation of Sydney as a
renminbi trading hub is welcome. Business accepts the challenge of
making all this work (Smith M.,
The FTA is a Great Deal, Now for the Hard Work, China Spectator,
18/11/14)
Todays' FTA with China has taken 10 years and complements other agreements
with Japan, the US, Korea, Singapore and NZ. China's share of Australia's
exports (32%) was greater than the other 5 combined (29%). Australians
living standards depend increasingly on China. Exports to all other countries
(including Japan) declined between 2008 and 2013. However at present exports to
China a starting to sag. While resource exports must eventually slow - their
prospects are still sound. However the FTA will now broaden the trade
relationship. The rise of China's middle class will be a big story over the next
decade - and the FTA will allow Australia to benefit (eg in terms of
agribusiness exports and inbound investment). For China it is all about everyone
benefiting from a growing pie. Australia needs to understand this and meet China
halfway. China needs to be seen as a partner rather than a just a customer (Laurensen
J., 'FTA
only a first step towards real partnership, China Spectator,
17/11/14)
And China's president made a case to Australia's parliament for the
development of such a partnership.
China's president (Xi Jinping) declared
that the 'big guy' / China is dedicated to pursuing peace and prosperity
in the Asia-Pacific in a speech that urged China and Australia to
jointly meet various security challenges in the region. Australia and
China should be harmonious neighbours who stick together. China's
intentions were peaceful, though there was a caveat that China would
firmly uphold its core interests (sovereignty / security / territorial
integrity). Hugh White (ANU) suggested that Xi was determined to be
positive - in contrast to US President Obama's dark view of the region's
prospects (which identified China with that dark future). Xi said many
people were uncertain / concerned about China - the big man in the
crowd. China is dedicated to peaceful development - a stable domestic
environment and a peaceful international environment. China is an
Asia-Pacific country - and without peace and prosperity in the region
stability and development in China can't be assured. China promotes
mutual benefit and inclusiveness and advocates a new vision of Asian
security to create a virtuous cycle of development and security. China
is prepared to dialogue / negotiate to maintain free navigation / peace
/ tranquility / cooperation. China and Australia should increase
dialogue - and work together. This would require increased mutual
understanding. There are no historic obstacles to a relationship between
China and Australia. Both want peace and cooperation / stability and
prosperity. This can go beyond commercial partnership to become a
strategic partnership. There are different histories / cultures / social
systems / stages of development - so disagreements must arise. This
requires candid talk, seeking common ground and meeting others halfway.
Development should be mutually reinforcing. China supported Australia's
northern development, and Australia's involvement in China's western
development. Two way investment should be increased. People to people
exchanges should increase. [Xi
gives reassuring message about China’s benign intentions , The
Conversation, 17/11/14]
A perspective on how China might view these arrangements can be gained from the
reported reactions to the FTA of: (a) Chinese officials; (b) an
Australian analyst concerned with strategic / political issues [1, 2]
and (c) an Australian observer involved in
developing trade and investment links with China.
Chinese analysts are now starting to explain the FTA. China expects 8 gains.
Increasing China's exports is the main issue - while diluting the US-led
Transpacific Partnership and promoting an APEC-focused Asia Pacific FTA is also
significant. The FTA also: reduces strategic pressure on China by showing that
China's rise is not a threat; promotes yuan internationalization; improves
access to good food products; expands investment opportunities; and makes it
easier for Chinese businesses to hire Chinese staff [1]
Australia's MP's strategic policies in Asia have not impeded his economic
agenda. An FTA with China has emerged despite Australia's alignment with Japan
and the US to resist China's regional ambitions. There are three possible
explanations: (a) China is more concerned with economic outcomes than with
strategic / political issues; (b) China cares about the strategic political
issues, but doesn't think that Australia's views matter; and (c) China does care
about both these issues and Australia's views, but prefers to use carrots to
sticks to bring Australia closer to China. Many in Canberra believe that (a) is
correct and that China is not really interested in challenging US leadership in
Asia. However that view is clearly invalid. The view that Australia does not
matter is also wrong - as Australia has been acquiring a prominent place in
regional power politics. Thus (c) seems most likely to be correct. Australia has
taken a long step away from endorsing what it had previously been saying - and
towards accepting Xi's vision of Asia's future under Chinese leadership. Whether
this will last is the question [1]
Why has China provided Tony Abbott with a FTA when Abbott has opposed
Beijing's political and strategic aspirations in Asia? Beijing was happy
to use the stick on others - which raises the question of why it has not
used carrots with others as it has so many to offer. It was suggested
(by Malcolm Cook) that the economic benefits of FTA to China outweigh
other issues. He concede that China is trying to create a new order in
Asia - and that Australia's attitude to this matters. However he argues
that economic considerations outweigh this. However it is more likely
that China's leaders believe that wider economic opportunities will
seduce Australia from alignment with China's strategic rivals - and thus
accept China's regional leadership. Both views may be right. It is hard
to see any really significant consequences of the FTA. It is possible
(though not probable) that China wants to use the FTA with Australia to
drive economic reform in China. The FTA is more likely to be about
politics than economics - in both Canberra and Beijing. Australia's PM
showed himself more open than before to China's vision of Asia's future.
It will be interesting to see how China responds. It would be nice to
think that Australia's economy matters a lot to China - but the reverse
is the case. China's economy is so important to Australia that this is
being used as a carrot to look kindly on China's aspirations for
regional leadership [1]
China has been seeking to create a new
international order because it had not been allowed to take an
appropriate place within established international institutions as the
result of a US belief that China was 'immature'. Elements of the
international order were perceived to involve: (a) making Renminbi an
international currency because of concern that a strengthening $US will
damage other economies; (b) creation of AIIB; (c) development of trade
relationships; and (d) efforts to contain official corruption.
Geo-political considerations were seen to impede the development of
benefits for the free trade arrangement that China and Australia were
proposing (see outline of
ASEAN, APEC and CHAFTA and resulting
Interchange with Daryl Guppy)
The Strategic Complexities
However it has also realistically been noted that for Australia to actually
get the benefits that the proposed FTA seems to offer would not be straightforward
because:
While the government is promoting a 'Free
Trade Agreement' with China, all that yet exists is a statement of
intent which will be time-consuming and complex to finalize (eg in
2016). And even then it would only be a 'preferential trade deal' - as
otherwise there would have been no need to negotiate details. Some have
seen China's offer to Australia of a 'comprehensive strategic
partnership' as like making someone 'employee of the month' rather than
giving them a pay rise. Some announced elements of the 'FTA' were
negotiated separately, while others were already in place. The
Opposition has been talking about revealing 'hidden nasties' - such as
eliminating tariffs on everything. The government has responded by
pointing to the need to end the 'age of entitlement'. Industry wants the
text of the proposed agreement to be released - but it is not yet
available [1]
The China FTA is a game changer. It improves the
business outlook and shows that Australia's relationship with traditional allies
has alienated China. Australian goods and services now have better links to
China and global markets. It is likely that mutual self-interest will pull
Australia and China closer together. The pull effect was very strong during
mining boom - as this was just a China boom. The FTA ensure that trade will
continue to increase. Australia will be pulled into China's business orbit - and
it will take a lot of effort by Australian businesses to break into Chinese
markets. Deeper integration with Chinese businesses will be required, and risky.
China's market is fragmented and highly competitive. Australian firms must now
invest in very long supply chains from Australia's countryside to China's minor
cities. Previously only a small number of multinationals were involved in
dealings with China. Now Chinese business competitors will increase in number
and sophistication and increase pressure on Australian service providers (eg
banks). Manufacturers will need to build personal relationships and
inter-organizational trust. Chinese investment in Australia is likely to
increase substantially. [1]
The FTA with China is generating excitement. China is seen to be sending a
powerful signal that it is prepared to open and do business with a developed
economy. Australian industry is reportedly shocked at the breadth and depth of
Chinese 'concessions'. It is seen to be better than other recent FTAs. Broader
claims are that: (a) China is using this FTA to show the world that it will do
business with a developed country using Australia as a starting point; or that
(b) China's president wants to use the FTA to expose China's economy to
international competition to hasten domestic reforms. It is generally assumed
that the FTA is positive for Australia, Chin and the liberal economic order -
because it is presumed that China is well on the way to opening domestic sectors
to outsiders. There are real benefits (eg access to Chinese markets for services
and agribusiness products). In return China has gained benefits - eg related to
reduced tariffs; more open investment access; and possible access by Chinese
workers. However , while there are benefits, something does not seem quite
right. For example China has given increased access for beef, but still has a
goal of having a beef / meat product exports industries. Australian rice and
wheat farmers gained no exemptions. China needs beef imports in the short term
but will build its domestic export capacity in the long term through technology
transfer gained while investing in production in Australia. A Chinese SOE was
very disappointed to miss out on buying Inghams because of this motivation.
China has frequently signed FTA. However even where tariffs are cut China then
imposes ad hoc regulatory hurdles to restrict imports of the government believes
that China is not 'winning' or for other political reasons). Domestic anti-trust
laws have been used against foreign companies threatening domestic competitors.
Licensing requirements have felled many foreign firms. China remains only partly
committed to free trade - as a tactical fix to improve the competitiveness of
China's firms. The key issue for China in the FTA is liberalization of its SOEs
from FIRB scrutiny - as this would facilitate takeovers to gain technology and
know-how. While the FTA is of value, its benefits should not be overstated - nor
should it be assumed that this indicates any dramatic domestic reform in China's
economy (Lee J.,
A reality check for the China-Australia FTA , China Spectator, 18/11/14)
Realpolitik (ie power / influence based on practical consideration rather
than ideology - is increasingly shaping the world. Australian investors face
competition from China. The latter have focused their efforts in Africa. China
is now Africa's largest trading partner. SOEs and wealthy Chinese individuals
are working in unison and crowding out foreigners. While Australia has been
negotiating a FTA with China, Africa is surrounded by free trade ports. While
China may be helping lift Africans out of poverty, it does no seem concerned
about the sources of ivory or diamonds. Chinese investors are now diversifying.
Australia's economy is so poorly developed that domestic investors have little
choice but to shift money off-shore - and they are increasingly collaborating
with those in Asia. The Asia-Pacific is becoming deeply integrated very rapidly
[1]
(CPDS note: China's wealthy are likely to have gained that
wealth through exploiting their positions within state-linked enterprises and
financial institutions - rather than through 'private' initiative)
Resource companies are not the only ones at risk if China's credit boom
bursts. Australia's banks should also be concerned - as they have doubled
investment to China since 2011 to over $1tr (according the BIS) just at the time
when investors elsewhere have been seeking to get out. While it is not certain
which sectors have gained this investment - it seems likely that much / most
will have gone to China's shadow banking system which is most at risk from
China's investment boom / bubble (Bell N.,
Too much, too late: Have Australian banks missed the boat on China?,
Business Day, 17/11/14)
Some in the real estate industry are concerned that large scale
Chinese real estate investors in Australia seem to acquire significant
sites at very high prices and just sit on them. Rather than seeking to
gain a profit (the goal of local property developers which requires them
to build on such sites quite soon) the motive seems to be merely to get
money out of Asia. The FTA lifts the level of such purchases that
are not subject to FIRB scrutiny from $54m to over $1bn. The effect of
such investments is not being considered by the various reviews that are
being conducted into the effect of Chinese investment in individual
properties [1].
CPDS Comment: This needs to be
considered in the light of
reports about:
(a) the huge quantities of cash that China's anti-corruption efforts
have reportedly caused corrupt officials to remove from China; and (b)
the apparent 'political' bias involved in China's anti-corruption
efforts (ie the 'princelings' who dominate China's current regime seem
to be exempt) - see also Overcoming
Australia's Corruption Shortage?
Also China has an autocratic / 'soft-fascist'
regime. It is ruled by educated elites through a process of building
collegiality and consensus within an hierarchical framework that encompasses
the society as a whole. This is in some ways similar to how effective
bureaucracies work internally in Western governments. There is however no reliable rule of law or any form of real accountability to
China's ordinary people. Its economic goals are quite
different to the independent profit-driven (ie capitalistic) aspirations that drive
industrial development
in liberal Western states. China’s economic aspirations appear to be
state-driven and mercantilist (ie to build economic, and therefore military, power) – see Understanding
East Asia's Neo-Confucian Systems of Socio-political-economy (2009).
China has been under huge pressure to change (see
Heading for a Crash or Meltdown)
but it can't be presumed that China's solution to its problems won't merely
involve doing other things the same way.
Moreover it appears highly unwise in dealings in East Asia to assess economic options separately from social,
political, military and even criminal considerations - because those considerations tend to be inter-related (ie to be dealt with by the
same state-centered networks).
The ‘non-capitalist’ financial systems that have underpinned economic
'miracles' in East Asia (ie those that don't emphasis return on capital) have
constituted a novel form of protectionism (see
Resist Protectionism: A Call That is Decades Too Late, 2010). They have
also imposed macroeconomic constraints on global growth
because reducing the risk of domestic financial crises required domestic 'financial repression'
which in turn required damaging international
financial imbalances if global growth was not to stall (see Structural
Incompatibility Puts Global Growth at Risk, 2003 and
Impacting the Global Economy,
2009). Those methods:
- continue to pose
significant global risks (see Creeping
Threats to Global Economy, 2014). The world is not facing a risk of
recession which would require counter-cyclical economic tactics (eg
stimulatory spending or easy money policies), but rather major
structural obstacles to ongoing economic growth;
- have left China exposed to a financial crisis (like that which Japan
suffered in the 1990s) which could also risk China's political
stability – see Assessing
China's Prospects (2014);
- can't easily be changed given the incompatibility between liberal
Western-style systems and China's cultural heritage (see
The Cultural Revolution needed in 'Asia' to Adapt to Western Financial
Systems, 1998).
In order to find a way out of (or to divert attention from) the strait-jacket
of the incipient financial crisis that has been tightening
since the GFC started, China seems to be trying to create a new international trade-tribute regime
like that by which Asia was administered from China prior to Western expansion
(see
Creating
a New International 'Confucian' Financial and Political Order). China's
so-called ‘Communist’ Party has operated as something like a pre-1911 Confucian
bureaucracy since the late 1970s – a fact which has now become very obvious (see
The Resurgence of Ancient
Authoritarianism in China).
As the former reference noted the FTA and proposed 'partnership' with Australia are only examples of a
significant number of initiatives
that seem to be being undertaken to place China at the center of a new international political and economic order that involves the
same sort of unrepresentative / illiberal practices that China's own people
are currently subjected to - in the hope that this will reduce the
risk of the financial failure that seems certain to bring down China's regime if
the disciplines of a liberal Western-style
international order continue to apply.
As noted above, economic and business observers
saw the FTA with China as being very beneficial to Australia economically.
However they did not seem to give any serious
consideration to the broader implications of that deal. As noted
above, analysts have been uncertain about whether the
FTA should be viewed as primarily an economic issue or as primarily a
political / strategic issue. And the present writer's suspicion is that both
these perspectives are necessary and overlapping.
The China-Australia FTA: Option 5 - email sent 28/11/14
Malcolm Cook
Institute of SE Asian Studies
Re: The
China-Australia FTA: Option 4, The Interpreter, 21/11/14
I noted the
reference to the above comments about the FTA in Hugh White’s
Why
economics doesn't explain China's FTA decision (China Spectator, 26/11/14)
and would like to put in my ‘two cents worth’ on the basis of an attempt
some years ago to reverse
engineer the intellectual basis of East Asian economic miracles.
As I
interpreted it you were suggesting that China’s primary motivation is to use
such FTA’s to drive change in its domestic economy.
I would like
to submit an alternative hypothesis, namely that China is engaging in a large
number of international efforts to boost economic collaboration (including the
FTA with Australia) in order to create a new international order because key
features of East Asian systems of socio-political-economy are: (a) very hard to
change because of incompatibilities between Western and East Asia cultural
traditions; and (b) likely to lead to catastrophic failure in a liberal Western
style international environment.
China is
exposed to the risk of a financial crisis as bad as, or worse than, that Japan
experienced as a result of Japan’s poorly-directed investment binge in the
1980s. This is compounded by domestic stresses associated with the way China’s
system works which are increasingly difficult to contain (eg the widespread
support for social equality which is incompatible with the social hierarchy that
is critical to China’s current system; and the likely increasing middle-class
demands for their preferred ways of doing things / ideas to be taken into
account) - see Heading
for a Crash or a Meltdown?
I suspect it
is possible that the numerous ‘economic cooperation’ endeavors that China is
promoting involve an attempt to create: (a) a ‘world-within-the world’ in
which China is the big / fearsome / fixer who can make things happen to
benefit the elites in other societies – which is similar to my
undoubtedly-improvable understanding the trade-tribute regime by which Asia was
administered from China prior to Western expansion; and (b) disrupt to liberal
post-WWII international economic and political order that the US and its allies
have championed under which China (and similar countries) are currently headed
for almost certain crisis. My thoughts on this are outlined in
Creating
a New International 'Confucian' Financial and Political Order
(2009+).
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations
John Craig
Another analyst suggested that the arrangement needed to be considered in
the light of a multi-pronged challenge to the pax Americana (ie the
international order based on free markets, liberal democracy and a rule of
law) that seems to be emerging (see Dupont A., 'On
the Brink of a New Cold World, The Australian, 29/11/14) and
that a there was thus a need for an overarching national security strategy.
And China's president's proposal for a
'comprehensive strategic partnership' with Australia posed a moral dilemma
for Australians in relation to whether benefits should be sought through
becoming insiders in an unrepresentative / authoritarian / elitist system.
His address to Australia's parliament spoke of China's
benign intentions - but also noted that: (a) that China is the 'big guy'; and (b)
the partnership would work through building relationships and seeking consensus.
The latter would involve working in the neo-Confucian / bureaucratic / 'Asian' way -
rather than the liberal democratic Western way that builds off the
capabilities of free individuals and concern for their welfare.
Australia's political leaders have sought to improve Australia's
relationship with China through dialogue with China's leaders without
apparently being aware that in 'East Asia' the traditional goal of such
interchanges is to manipulate others'
actions, while making it hard for others to understand what is actually
going on (see The Limits to Dialogue and
A Diplomatic Coup in Beijing: By Who? ).
Deception is the core of traditional
Art of War strategies. Reliable
understanding requires looking closely at what is actually being done, not
listening to what is being said.
Governments need to make it clear to Australia’s people whether these factors have been carefully considered by those developing the
proposed FTA, and will be considered by those negotiating any prospective 'partnership' with China. Such arrangements
are potentially a good idea – providing the community fully understands what it
is getting involved with and is thus in a position to constructively influence
the relationship rather than becoming a victim. This does not yet seem to be the
case.
Australia's prime minister thanked China's president for an historic
statement at a dinner in his honour about China becoming fully democratic by
2050. However Mr Abbott had misunderstood China's leader. Xi had referred to
turning China into a modern socialist country that is prosperous, democratic,
culturally advanced and harmonious by the middle of the century. China experts
worldwide have pointed out that Abbott had not understood what was said. China's
leaders only refer to democracy within their one party system. At best this
might evolve into something like Singapore's semi-democracy. Abbott was probably
inadequately briefed and lacked the context to understand Xi's words. [1]
|
Ending Australia's Political Paralysis? |
Ending Australia's Political Paralysis? - email sent 6/2/15
Norman Abjorensen,
Australian National University
Re: Conservatives
in Crisis, Inside Story, 3/2/15
Your article suggests that the current turmoil in the
‘conservative’ political camp reflects that the fact that the
‘conservatives’ represent privileged interests, and that they have failed to
gain broader electoral appeal.
I would like to suggest by contrast that it is Australia
that is in crisis – and that, until some serious institutional reforms are put
in place, any political faction that gains power is likely to be on a slippery
slope to quick electoral defeat.
There has recently been an extremely unusual electoral
slaughter of a first term government in Queensland. And the federal conservative
administration is trying to work out how it can avoid the same fate. However the
crisis that they face parallels what their Labor predecessors faced. Consider,
for example, the federal ALP’s perception that the Rudd Government had ‘lost
its way’ (eg see Testing
the ALP’s Patience, 2010), and the inability of Mr Rudd’s Labor
successor (Julia Gillard) and her successor
(Kevin Rudd) to stabilize the situation. And
consider the Queensland Beattie Government’s repeated need to apologize for,
and throw vast amounts of money at,
its crises [1,
2] and
its simultaneous escalation of at-times-dubious infrastructure spending that left Queensland
with spiraling debts that now seriously constrain government options (see
Queensland’s
Debt Binge, 2012), and the inability of Mr Beattie’s Labor successor (Anna
Bligh) to achieve her apparent goal of stabilizing government (see
Queensland’s
Next Successful Premier, 2007).
There are underlying problems that afflicted both the Labor
administrations and their Conservative successors. Australia’s system of
government has been struggling to cope with the challenges it faces (eg see
Reconsidering
the Origins of Kevin Rudd’s Failure (2010) and
Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+). The latter
refers, for example, to: increased complexity which tends to be hard to handle
through a democratic process; weakened public service support to governments (eg
through politicisation); trying to be ‘business-like’ about government’s
primarily non-business-like functions; distortions of government operations
through the centralization implicit in federal fiscal imbalances; and the
retreat into insubstantial political populism because anything else seemed too
hard. Similar comments on the history of the breakdown of effective
governance in Queensland, and what might be done about it, were in
Reversing
Queensland's Institutional Decay (2013).
And Australia’s economy has operated for much of the past
decade on the basis of a ‘stronger for longer resource boom hypothesis’ (ie
that, in contrast to past boom bust cycles, the resources boom and the jobs and
revenue it generates would continue indefinitely) – see
Do
Blind Spots Cloud the RBAs Lucky Country Vision (2011). A structural deficit
was put in place in the federal budget in about 2006 by committing
boom-era capital gains tax revenues to tax cuts and income transfers (see
Global
financial crisis, 2009). The importance of creating a foundation for
diversifying Australia’s resource-dependent economy, which had been
universally acknowledged in the 1980s, was forgotten.
Moreover the methods used to facilitate economic diversification had been
inadequate (see
Defects in Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes,
2000+ and
Lifting Productivity: Considering the Bigger Picture,
2010+) and had had serious unintended consequences (see
Neglected Side Effects,
2004). And, as the commodity boom
has unwound, large revenue shortfalls have escalated budgetary deficits. Also in
diversifying its economy Australia now faces competition from
increasingly-economically-capable emerging economies with lower tax rates and
lesser public service / income transfer expectations. Thus at the very least
Australia faces a significant economic
challenge (eg see How
Durable is Australia's Luck?).
And the signs of increasing global financial, economic and
political instability suggests that Australia’s challenges will be compounded
(see An
Approaching Crisis). For example:
- a major constraint on global growth arguably lies in a deficiency
in final demand that quantitative easing can’t correct (eg see ‘Roubini:
Why QE isn’t working’, CNBC. 1/2/15). And that demand deficiency
seem largely (though not solely) a by-product of structural incompatibilities
between Western and East Asian financial and economic systems (eg see
Putting
the Economic Risk of Deflation in Context, 2015 and
Structural
Incompatibility Puts Global Growth at Risk, 2003);
- the demand deficiencies that have been vital to the methods used
to achieve economic ‘miracles’ in East Asia have made the world economy
dependent on easy money policies (eg see Impacting
the Global Economy, 2009). Those monetary policies have had nasty side
effects in terms of: encouraging ever higher levels of public debt (often
making them unsustainable when interest rates normalize); increasing
politically-destabilizing social inequality by feeding asset inflation; encouraging resource
misallocation; and increasing the risk of financial instability (and of massive
CPI inflation in the event of a ‘real-economy’ recovery);
- China, whose strong debt-driven commodities’ demand allowed
Australia to largely avoid the effects of the GFC, seems to be headed for
problems that could be even worse than Japan suffered from 1990 for somewhat
similar reasons (see China:
Heading for a Crash or a Meltdown, 2010+).
Governments have seemed unaware (or unwilling to tell the
electorate) that Australia has a real economic problem. The electorate wants
things to be ‘good’ – but has no real way to know what is needed to get
‘good’ outcomes. Governments have continued to promise ‘good things’ to
the electorate – while trying to come to grips with their declining fiscal
capacity to meet public expectations in the face of revenue weaknesses and
escalating demands (eg due to population aging). Governments have
also seemed unaware (or unwilling to tell the electorate) that serious
weaknesses have been introduced into Australia’s machinery of government (eg
see
Decay
of Australian Public Administration, 2002).
Much stronger institutions are needed to address these
problems. For example, the politicisation of public services that has
allowed
insubstantial political populist’s to gain public support needs to be
ended. And civil institutions need to enable the electorate to understand: (a)
that it has problems – and what its problems really are; (b) that governments
on their own lack both the resources to solve those problems, and the ability to
free themselves electorally from interest group demands that they do so; (c)
that Australia’s system of government needs overhaul; and (d) how the
community itself can take more initiative in solving its social, economic and
governance problems (eg see A
Case for Innovative Economic Leadership).
Developing stronger institutional support to Australia
democratic political system would not be an alternative to ongoing government
operations. It needs to happen concurrently. This would require careful
management, but would not be impossible.
Until stronger institutional support exists, state and
federal administrations of any political flavour must continue to stagger from
crisis to crisis (and to early electoral death). In 2012 it seemed
likely that Queensland’s next unsuccessful premier would be whoever was
unlucky enough to lead the party that won that year’s state election (see
Queensland's
Next Unsuccessful Premier, 2012). The same is true in 2015 - as the only
real difference now is that the state’s economic challenges have become harder
and the LNP’s ‘lease-assets’ option for dealing with the state’s fiscal
constraints has been proven politically unacceptable (eg see
Queensland
Economic Policy Issues, 2015 and The
Black Holes in LNP and Labor Economic Agendas, 2015). And there
is nothing really different about Australia’s national government. Any future
Prime Minster who does not want to share their recent predecessors’ ignominy
will have to pay serious attention to overcoming weaknesses in governments’
institutional support (eg as suggested in
Australia's
Next Successful Prime Minister, 2012).
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations
John Craig
|
Insubstantial Election Campaigns are only a Symptom of Australia's Political
Malaise |
Insubstantial Election Campaigns are only a Symptom of Australia's Political Malaise - email sent 13/2/15
Carol Johnson (University of Adelaide) and
John Wanna (ANU)
Re: Mantras,
manipulation and mandates , Inside Story, 13/2/15
Your article
suggested that the seeds of the present federal political malaise were laid in
the 2013 election campaign which was a battle of catch phrases not supported by
much in the way of policy detail or substance. This certainly seemed to be
the case at that time (see Get
Ready for Coalition Chaos, 2013)
However there
was nothing unusual about the 2013 federal election campaign in this respect
(see On
Populism, 2007 and The
Need for Running Repairs to the Ship of State, 2013). The lack of substance
in political rhetoric had been blindingly obvious for years. Oppositions have
been winning elections mainly on the basis of the manifest incompetence of their
predecessors. And in the absence of any realistic policy agenda incoming
administrations have had a choice between making dubious decisions or conducting
endless inquiries (see The
Choice Between Evils that Governments Now Face: 'Process Addiction' or Bad
Decisions, 2013).
In Queensland that devilish choice can be traced back to
the mid-1990s (see Queensland’s
Worst Government, 2005). The 1989-1996 Goss Government ‘reformed’
Queensland’s government machinery in the same way that many other did in that
era (ie it replaced public service expertise and experience with political
motivation and ‘yes men’). Its inability then to actually achieve anything
led to the unexpected electoral success of the
Borbidge Government. The latter then found that it needed about 90 inquiries
before it would be in a position to make reliable decisions. Those inquiries
were all reporting at about the time that the Borbidge Government was voted out
because of its inactivity. It was replaced by the Beattie administration in 1998
which apparently decided that it had to ‘just do things’ even though no one
was really certain about what to do. Many publicly-visible crises emerged and
required apologies, and the groundwork was laid for a blow-out in Queensland
government debts by ‘solving’ crises with large cash injections and
accelerating sometimes-dubious capital spending beyond levels that were likely
to be sustainable. A political commitment was famously made to a new dam for SE
Queensland even if it was not feasible. And when its proved non-feasible, the
state was out some hundreds of millions of dollars. The 2007-2012 Bligh
Government seemed sensibly to want to prevent crises rather than throw money at
them, but struggled to do so – partly because of Queensland’s increasingly
difficult fiscal position. The 2012-2015 Newman Government resurrected the
Beattie administration’s ‘just do it’ style (with a different political
orientation) and found winning a second term to be hard. And it’s (presumably Palaszczuk
Government) successor now
appears very likely to face both the Borbidge Government’s 1996 predicament (ie
gaining power unexpectedly with no serious policy agenda) and serious fiscal
constraints.
I should thus like to submit for your consideration that
Australia’s political malaise has a structural / institutional cause –
rather than being a consequence of the way election campaigns are conducted (for
reasons suggested in Ending
Australia's Political Paralysis?, 2015). Changing circumstances and
unconsidered consequences of past ‘reforms’ have rendered governments
increasingly ineffectual. Significant ‘repairs to the ship of state’ are
well overdue.
John Craig
|
Australia's Lack of Strategic Leadership: Addressing the Causes |
|
Yes, The System is Broke |
Yes, The System is Broke - email sent 19/9/15
Niki Savva
Re: No,
the system ain’t broke, The Australian, 19/9/15
I must differ with the theme of your article. Australia
suffers serious systemic problems in dealing with its current challenges. These
difficulties arise primarily from inadequate institutional support to political
leaders and from community, business and political expectations that the federal
government can, and should, be primarily responsible for solving them. Prime
ministers are being asked to do the impossible. Quickly discarding them when
they fail to live up to those expectations solves nothing.
My
Interpretation of your article: Some
see Australia’s system as broken because there have been five prime ministers
in 5 years. Alternately it can be seen that the system has worked by weeding out
incapable leaders. Several incapable leaders were replaced recently –
but the same system sustained Bob Hawke and John Howard. The main
difference now is the social media and the 24 hour news cycle. Both Hawke and
Howard experienced difficulties initially but overcame these because of the
experience they brought to the job; their temperament; their adherence to proper
process; their ability to attract good staff; their ability to sift advice; and
their commitment to reform. Good process improves the prospects of
success. None of what has happened is the result of flawed system – but
rather of flawed people in it. It was recently suggested that the GFC both made
Kevin Rudd and broke him – because it gave him a reason for being and led to a
centralised method of operation and poor cabinet processes. Some see the trouble
with Rudd and Gillard as that they thought they were smarter than others – but
did not know what they did not know. Rudd Gillard and Abbott were also
pressured by media changes – ie by a speeded-up news cycle. It would be
unforgiveable if Turnbull joined them. There have been significant changes
to Australia’s prime minister at various times in the past.
My reasons for suggesting that ‘the system is broke’
are outlined in Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+). This
suggests many reasons for recognising that the system that worked fairly well in
the past (eg for Hawke and Howard) has become unworkable now. For example, the
democratic process itself faces growing structural difficulties associated with:
(a) greater complexity which often makes it impossible
to find simple 'rational' policy and program options and instead requires incremental / decentralised adjustments;
(b) globalization which constrains what governments can influence and
requires understanding the practical consequences of radically-different
cultures; (c) the damage to machinery of government through ill-advised reform
(eg by the Hawke and Howard administrations); (d) the rising influence of
idealists who have not understood the importance of experience in developing
practical policy; and (e) the populism (ie announcing whatever sounds trendy
without much concern for whether it is practical) that political leaders have
often resorted to cope with their predicament.
There are various other issues mentioned in that document
that suggest the need for steady institutional reform, and that merely
installing leaders with the latest ‘great ideas’ is unlikely to produce
significantly better results.
As suggested in the section of that document on A
Nation Building Agenda, two of the requirements to overcome these
constraints are arguably to reverse:
- The loss of competence associated with public service politicisation
and 'efficiency' reforms that were not
based on experience of what governments actually do; and
- The expectation that the federal government can, or should, be the
primary source of solutions to Australia’s challenges.
In relation to the former, it can be noted that a
significant (though not the only) cause of the loss of competent internal
support to government was the application of business-like methods to
government’s primarily-non-business like functions (eg see
Decay
of Australian Public Administration, 2002). Unfortunately those who pressed
for those dysfunctional ‘reforms’ have been slow to realize that they
didn’t know what they didn’t know about what was required for governments to
govern (eg see S-L-O-W
Learners, 2010).
And, though some progress has started to be made in
reducing reliance on central planners by engaging state leaders in making
decisions related to reforming Australia’s tax system, there is still a long
way to go (see Australia's
Future Tax System: The Cost of the Financial Crisis and the Opportunity to Fix
Government, 2009; Fixing
Australia’s Federation, 2010;
Infrastructure
Obstacles and Opportunities: Submission to Productivity Commission , 2014;
and Australia’s
Infrastructure Incompetence, 2015).
Also, while it is still recognised that Australia future
international competitiveness depends on developing its innovation capabilities,
it does not seem to be recognised that:
- more-of-the-same methods that have been used in the hope of
achieving this over the past 3 decades won’t be enough.
It is not enough to create an 'efficient'
market economy. It also must be a 'developed' economy, and this does
not automatically exist - though there are ways to accelerate its
emergence (ie to have an 'economic miracle'). However
leadership in creating (say) an effective market-responsive innovation system can’t
be provided by democratically-accountable institutions (eg see
Australia’s
Competitiveness Some Suggestions, 2013). And
unfortunately there is strong
resistance by those who need to provide leadership to doing so because of
resource-cursed Australians' traditional preference for reliance on natural resource wealth and on governments
to redistribute it. Likewise lobbying governments to ‘do something’ about
social dysfunctions (such as domestic violence) seems to have become the main
mission of many institutions who would themselves need to take the lead if an environment
is to be restored in which such social dysfunctions are less common-place than
they have become while individuals can remain free of
moral legalism (see
General
Observations about ‘Is the Smart State a Just State?, 2003 and
Christian
Foundations of Liberal Western Institutions, 2010);
- Without a dramatic increase in access to strategic intelligence
about what is happening elsewhere, competitiveness is unlikely to be
significantly improved (see also Australia's
Lack of Strategic Leadership: Addressing the Causes, 2015). The world has
been being assumed to be like it was (eg see Australia
in the Clayton's Century: The 'Asian' Century you have when you are not having
an Asian Century, 2012) and thus allow
traditional economic principles to guide the development of effective policy.
However this is not so. The growth and stability of the world economy are
at risk because of an unprecedented debt
burden sustained by the ultra-low and
dysfunctional interest rates which have been made necessary largely by the
international financial imbalances associated with the non-capitalist financial
systems of East Asia’s major economies (eg see
Impacting
the Global Economy, 2009 and An
Approaching Crisis - From Late 2013). China (on whose
economy Australia has become highly dependent): (a) has been seeking to create a
new authoritarian international order as an alternative to the ‘liberal’
order that the US has championed since WWII because of the cultural obstacles
that exist in East Asia to operating within a ‘liberal’ institutional
framework (see Creating
a New International 'Confucian' Financial and Political Order, 2008+); and
(b) seems likely to be facing a major crisis because of associated structural
difficulties in generating capital for investment without its past reliance on
escalating debts (see
Ongoing Uncertainty and Context
to China's Share Market Boom and Bust, 2015).
Suggestions about the need to strengthen Australia’s
institutions were also made in 2012 when Julia Gillard was being pressured to
stand down to make way for a stronger candidate (see
Australia’s
Next Successful Prime Minister). However no one seemed to be
interested.
John Craig
|
Ignorance and Incompetence is the Biggest Enemy of Reform |
Ignorance and Incompetence is the Biggest Enemy of Reform - email sent 23/9/15
Paul Kelly
The Australian
Re: Negative
Politics the Biggest Enemy of Reform, The Australian, 23/9/15
Your article acknowledged that there are systemic obstacles
to Australia’s political system dealing effectively with current challenges.
However it implied that most of those difficulties related to the role of the
media. In Yes,
The System is Broke I suggested that the problem was far broader. I would
like to illustrate this point further with an example below related to public
service effectiveness. In relation to this it is also noted that in
2010 there were other observers who suggested the existence of systemic problems
– none of which emphasised media influences (see The
Need for Nation Building).
By way of background, my career involved strategic policy
R&D in Queensland – ie trying to identify things that were ‘coming at’
government / Queensland in order to stimulate a timely response (see
CV).
One thing that became very obvious was that the democratic
political system was always out-of-date in understanding of emerging
opportunities and challenges and tended to over-simply issues. This is to be
expected as policy issues tend to be very complex and the political system tends
to reflect ‘everyman’s’ understanding rather than leading-edge-expert
knowledge. None-the-less democratic politics plays a very useful role and (given
competent support) those limitations can be overcome.
However in the 1970s the Whitlam Government encountered
severe difficulties in implementing its idealistic but impractical social /
economic / governance reform agenda – and this was seen to be the result of
public service ‘resistance’ rather than political over-simplification. The
Royal Commission into Australian Government Administration which subsequently
looked at that administration’s frustration concluded that the need was to
make public services unquestioningly compliant with political agendas –
because the fact that the Whitlam Government’s agendas had been impractical
was most obvious to those (not including the Royal Commission) with a high level
of relevant knowledge and experience.
Taking a lead from the Royal Commission, the standard
process for ‘reform’ of public services then came to involve a ruthless
insistence that practical defects in political agenda were not to be
highlighted. This lead to serious failures by idealistic reformist state
administrations (eg see
The
Fall of the House of Cain, 1992 and
Towards
Good Government in Queensland, 1995) – and somewhat similar
arrangements were later put in place by the Howard Government at the federal
level. The lack of an adequate reality check on idealistic but
impractical political agendas has remained a feature of government in Australia
ever since – with devastating consequences (eg see
The
Growing Case for Professionalism, 2001+ and
On Populism, 2007+).
This point is of current relevance because essentially
everything that the current federal government (and opposition) believe is
appropriate to dealing with Australia’s current challenges and opportunities
involves over-simplifications that need to be subjected to a reality-check that
it is highly unlikely that public services are currently equipped to provide.
15-20 years of career stability would be required to build up the required depth
of knowledge and experience, and this has not been available.
Ways to reduce this and other systemic obstacles to
effective governance in Australia were speculated in A
Nation Building Agenda (2008).
John Craig
|
Australia's State and Territory Governments Want a 'Republic' - Whatever
That Means |
Australia's State and Territory Governments Want a 'Republic' - Whatever That Means - email sent 26/1/16
Tom Allard
Sydney Morning Herald
Re: 'We
want a republic': Australia's states and territory leaders are united,
Brisbane Times, 25/1/16
State / territory politicians may be united in wanting a ‘republic’. But
they have not suggested what a workable ‘republic’ would involve (eg would
it involve an elected or appointed head of state). This matters because
with an elected head of state, extensive constitutional and
machinery-of-government changes would be needed to avoid dangerous political
instability. This failure to be open with the public about the ‘republic’
issue is another example of the lack of practical realism that governments have
degenerated into that is preventing Australia’s increasingly serious
challenges being competently addressed.
My
Interpretation of your article: State
and territory leaders unanimously back Australia becoming a republic – ie for
an Australia head of state. However divisions remain over when the change should
be made. State and territory leaders signed a declaration to end constitutional
monarchy as part of an Australian Republican Movement campaign. The declaration
was that ‘Australia should have an Australian head of state’. The Australian
Republican Movement chairman (Peter FitzSimons) said that overwhelming political
support for a republic was significant. The Prime Minister, Malcolm Turnbull,
continued to support the change to a republic – but believes that there are
other more important issues at present. Mr FitzSimons wants a plebisite in 2020.
The vote would be followed by a congress of political and community leaders to
choose a preferred republican model – and to support whatever model was then
democratically supported at a referendum. Mr FitzSimons backs a minimalist
republican model whereby the governor general would be nominated by the prime
minister, approved by parliament and then become head of state. This would
replace governor-general being appointed by the British sovreign on
recommendation of the prime minister. Others favour direct election of a
president. Disagreement over this was a factor in the failure of 1999 republic
referendum. Of 54 Commonwealth nations, 33 have become republics under Queen
Elizabeth.
A proposal for the appointment an Australian as head
of state was put to the electorate in 1999 and rejected apparently because the
majority either: (a) supported retention of links to the British monarchy; or
(b) wanted the head of state’s position to be filled by direct election.
However direct election would be incompatible with Australia’s constitution
because it would politicise the head of state’s role (for reasons suggested in
Politicization
of the ‘Crown’, 2003+).
Australia’s constitution is built around an apolitical
head of state (ie Australian representatives of the hereditary British
monarchy). The head of state holds ALL executive power but exercises that power
solely on the advice of elected executive governments (providing doing so
conforms with the constitution). There would be a risk of political instability
if a (say) ‘president’ were elected. The electorate would judge potential
presidents in terms ‘political’ criteria and the president’s political
agenda would either conflict or coincide with the agenda of the elected
executive government. As an elected president would then have their own
‘legitimate’ political power base, conflicts or conspiracies could arise in
the exercise of executive power.
Creating a workable Australian republic would seem to
require either:
- appointing someone to play an apolitical role similar to
that of the current Governor General / Governors – as proposed in the 1999
referendum and now endorsed (your article suggests) by the head of the Australia
Republican Movement; or
- electing the head of state and making sweeping changes to
the constitution and system of government so that politicisation of that role
does not lead to instability. This might, for example, involve adopting
something like the US system where the elected head of state also heads the
government executive and is counterbalanced by a much stronger (and independent)
legislative branch.
State and territory leaders (and others) are being
irresponsible by merely advocating a ‘republic’ without clearly identifying
whether or not this would be associated with an elected head of state (and thus
whether major across-the-board changes to the constitution and machinery of
government would also be needed).
Australia’s machinery of government has long been in
desperate need of repair (for reasons suggested in
Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+). The latter
referred to the need for: (a) much stronger support to Australia’s political
processes to enable them to be competent and effective; and (b) the use of
alternative apolitical methods for addressing society’s challenges and
opportunities. And given significant current domestic social [1,
2,
3,
4,
5],
economic [1,2,
3]
and budgetary [1,
2]
challenges (as well as international economic [1]
and political [1,
2,
3]
instabilities and risks that compound them), there is now a desperate need for
governments to become much more competent and effective than they have been in
recent years. Nothing will be achieved so long as established
interests believe that it is in their political interest to keep the public
ignorant of the nature of, and uninvolved in actually dealing with, the real
challenges and opportunities Australia faces.
Advocating removal of the stabilizing influence of the
British monarchy as the foundation of Australia’s system of constitutional
government, without clearly identifying what it should be replaced with, would
not be a constructive step – as was reportedly suggested also by one federal
MP, Andrew Nikolic (Kelly J., and Coultan M., ‘Bill
Shorten taps Malcolm Turnbull’s instincts to stir republican pot, The
Australian, 26/1/16)
John Craig
|
Justifying the Opinions of 'Australians of the Year' |
Justifying the Opinions of 'Australians of the Year' - email sent 27/1/16
Miranda Devine,
Daily Telegraph
Re: Sorry
David, but it’s the wrong fight, Daily Telegraph, 26/1/16
Your article was critical of the Australian of the Year
process on the grounds that you believe it has become
a plaything of ‘social engineers’
who ‘reflect all the unhealthy preoccupations of the Left’ – and tends to
result in Australians being lectured on what is wrong with them. You were
especially critical of the selection of former Army chief David Morrison for
2016 – on the grounds that (despite having been Chief of Army for four years)
he had: (a) said that he didn’t ‘think that there was a military solution to
anything’; and (b) given flowery speeches decrying masculinity and patriarchy
instead of providing the leadership that front-line soldiers needed.
If the effect of being selected as Australian of the Year
is (as you suggest) to give individuals a platform for expressing their personal
opinions about matters of possible
public concern, those responsible for the Australian of the Year process
surely need to establish a means whereby the reasons underlying those opinions
can be made publicly accessible, and then publicly debated.
For example one of the David Morrison’s opinions that you
mentioned probably has substance that is only apparent to those who have studied
the issue in depth. There seems to have been widespread recognition over the
last few years by security / defence analysts that there are (as Morrison
reportedly stated) limits to ‘military solutions’ to the world’s problems.
Some suggestions about why that conclusion can be seen as reasonable are
outlined in Muslims
Must Lead the ISIS Fight - But Muslim Armies Can't. The latter points to the
fact that defeating Islamist extremism primarily requires discrediting
Islamist
ideology in the minds of Muslim communities – and that military forces can’t
be expected to do this.
Those who aspire to lead national opinion (as Australians
of the Year seem to want to do) can’t be effective if they are forced to
compress complex strategic conclusions into the one-liners that suit media
interviews.
The need for an arrangement for Australians of the Year
(and those who receive other Australia Day awards) to present the rationale for
what would otherwise be ‘one-liner’ opinions can also be illustrated by
other complex issues. For example:
Finally in relation to your concern that the Australian of
the Year process at present simply allows individuals to pressure others to
comply with their perceptions of appropriate moral standards, I should
like to suggest (if so) it is anything but unique in that respect (see
Restraining
Liberty, 2003+). The latter identifies increasing moral authoritarianism by
political / community leaders that is putting Australia’s traditional and
advantageous liberal social, economic and political institutions at risk.
The opportunity that the winners of Australia Day awards
have to raise issues of public concern should surely be transformed into a
vehicle for rational debate - rather than merely being a way for award winners
to present themselves as moral elites.
John Craig
|
Morrison Highlighted the Need for Research Into The Causes of Muslims'
Problems
|
Morrison Highlighted the Need for Research Into The Causes of Muslims' Problems - email sent 2/2/16
Kuranda Seyit,
Forum on Australia’s Islamic Relations
Re: Morrison
the cure for Islamophobia, On Line Opinion, 1/2/2016
Your article suggested that:
“David
Morrison recently pointed out that religious discrimination in Australia is
without doubt alive and well. He was referring to Muslims in particular ….
(and) ….. When he spoke out against this vile trend called Islamaphobia, he
silenced its proponents … (and) …. When the Australian of the Year
says, "We need to understand the challenges that they face", then
that's code for "Hey you bigots stop your hate, stop your attempts to ruin
this great country". That's code for bigotry no longer has a home in
Australia. Stop!”.
There is no doubt that Morrison implied that religious
discrimination (which you described as ‘Islamophobia’) is the main source of
the problems that Muslims face in Australia. However there is a clear need for a
reliable way for such opinions to be properly assessed (see Justifying
the Opinions of 'Australians of the Year'). As the latter suggested, issues
about which Morrison expressed an opinion (such as whether religious
discrimination is the primary source of Muslims’ problems) can be anything but
clear cut. The complexities of those issues are further illustrated in
Muslims'
Problems are Not Limited to Islamist Extremism, and Can't Be Solved Simply by
Reclaiming Islam's Past Intellectual Traditions. The latter involved
comments on concerns expressed by a reputable Islamic scholar about ‘the
crisis facing Islam’ – a crisis that he did not seem to believe had its
origins in ‘Islamophobia’.
David Morrison himself illustrated the need for some mechanism to
validate the opinions of Australians of the Year. He reportedly gladly pointed
out that another issue on which he had expressed an opinion (ie an Australian
republic) was more complex than he had originally indicated – ie because
of “the practical difficulties of arriving at a satisfactory model for a
republic” (Baxendale R., David
Morrison ‘stole’ best line from David Hurley’, The Australian,
2/2/16).
Thus (as suggested in Justifying
the Opinions of 'Australians of the Year') it seems important to improve the
processes associated with the Australia Day honours to ensure that those given
favoured platforms to express their opinions have the opportunity to properly
justify them.
Regards
John Craig
Unsolicited Response from 'Michael'
to a copy of the above received 2/2/16
Let me get this straight, Muslims believe they
are the victims of intolerance ?
The Jewish community have been the prime targets
from Muslim extremists [ to be PC] for many years. As Muslim immigration
has increased out of all proportion so to has Anti - Semitism , threats
to Jews . In fact the problem has become so great that our security has
just been further upgraded our Jewish Day schools have now armed guards,
One of the largest Jewish day schools in Sydney in Bondi has just had a
'Bomb proof ' fence erected and the main Jewish community Centre in
Caulfield Melbourne is about to erect a bomb proof wall around the
premises.
All visiting Israeli Politicians, Musicians,
Artists, sportspeople { tennis players Inc ] and Jewish speakers must
have security .
All this because of Potential so called Lone wolf
Muslim attackers.
When The Age Editor last night came to the Jewish
Community Centre to address the Jewish community he had to go through
security .
I can assure you the Muslim community does not
require this type of security and they are not afraid of Jewish
Extremists wanting to blow up their Mosques or kill their flock!
The mantra that it is only a small minority of
bad apples is rubbish .It only took 20 Bad apples in New York a few each
in London, Paris , Turkey and only one bad apple in Sydney. The cost and
inconvenience to the Jewish community and the infringement on our human
rights for having to live under siege is unacceptable and it make no
difference when the majority do nothing and claim to be the victims !
There is a word if Jewish called Chutzpah [cheek]
that is what I call the Muslims claiming to be the victims!
|
Improving Democracy
|
Improving Democracy - email sent 6/2/16
Michael Cope,
Qld Council of Civil Liberties
Re:
Remeikis A., Queensland
must say no to four-year terms until democracy improves: QCCL, Brisbane
Times, 3/2/16
You were quoted as referring to the need
to improve Queensland’s democratic processes. I should like to put forward
some observations and suggestions about this on the basis of long term
public-service involvement in seeking to improve the effectiveness of government
in Queensland (see CV) –
and subsequent continuation of an interest in that issue in both a Queensland
and a broader context (see CPDS
Web-site).
The democratic process is only part of
machinery of government in Queensland / Australia. For example, effective
democracy requires: (a) well developed capabilities in civil institutions (eg
research bodies, associations, universities) to provide practical and up-to-date
inputs to policy debates; as well as (b) knowledgeable / experienced
professional civil services (to provide a ‘reality check’ on policy
proposals and competent support with implementation).
Weaknesses in those other areas will make
an effective democratic process impossible. Proposals for ‘political’ reform
that do not build on (and build up) those external and internal support
capabilities risk merely generating practical failures that discredit whatever
goals reformers might have had for the ‘political’ aspects of government
machinery.
Examples: This can be illustrated by the failed attempt at reform
of Queensland’s machinery of government by the Goss administration in the
early 1990s following the Fitzgerald Inquiry’s late 1980’s exposure of
political / police corruption (see
Toward
Good Government in Queensland,
1995). Complete political disregard of
the need for knowledgeable and experienced public service support resulted in
machinery of government that was ineffectual and this seriously hampered the
performance of subsequent administrations (see
Queensland’s
Worst Government?
2005). It also created an easy target for those who sought to profit from abuses
of power (see
Reform
of Queensland Institutions – or a Rising Tide of Public Hypocrisy?, 2004).
This was ironic as inhibiting corruption had been the focus of the Fitzgerald Inquiry whose
goals the Goss Government had believed that it was giving effect to – but
without recognising that merely creating new institutions whose names implied
that they were the ‘solution’ would not be enough (see
Journey
Towards a More Effective ‘Fitzgerald Inquiry’, 2009 and
Independent
Commissions Are Not Enough to Contain Political Corruption, 2013).
Similar ‘reforms’, dominated by primarily
‘political’ considerations rather than practical performance, led to the
failure of other Australian administrations in the same era – and to serious
ongoing limitations on the effectiveness of governments in Australia generally
(see
The
Decay of Australian Public Administration, 2002). Public services’ ‘responsiveness’ and
‘managerialism’ (that saw management as a generalist function requiring no
depth of knowledge of the area being managed) was emphasized by political
factions who lacked practical experience of government and up-to-date knowledge
of government functions. This led to public services dominated by yes-men –
which was anything but a formula for competence.
The
absence of professional (ie experienced / knowledgeable) public services led to
many problems, such as:
And a significant ongoing feedback effect arguably
developed between weakening public sector agencies and weakening the economic
strategies that governments’ adopted (see
Broken
Governance and Ineffectual Economic Strategy: Two Sides of the Same Coin?, 2015).
This, needless to say, exacerbated governments’ budgetary challenges.
Proposals
some years ago for improving Queensland’s political system (by changes to the
legislature) were well intended but would have achieved little without
substantial complementary enhancement of the external and internal support the
‘political’ system requires to: (a) know what to do; and (b) put policies
into practice (see
The
Upper House Solution: A Commentary (2006).
A serious problem is that Queensland /
Australian civil institutions have traditionally had limited ability to provide
reliable (ie practical and up-to-date) inputs to the political system (eg see
Queensland’s
Weak Parliament,
1999) because: (a) Queensland / Australia has suffered a ‘resource curse’ in
that economic performance has depended much more on natural wealth than on the
strategic knowledge and competencies of local commercial / civil institutions;
and (b) Australia’s machinery of government was inherited from the UK rather
than developed locally – so naive mistakes have been made in the advice given
to the political system about machinery of government issues.
Examples: The belief that the use of competition and
business-like methods in undertaking governments’ primarily-non-businesslike
functions should be emphasized to boost Australia’s economic productivity
resulted in the severe weakening of the collaboration and competencies required
to support governments’ core role (ie ‘governing’) – eg see
Governing
is Not Just Running a Large Business, 2002+ and
Neglected
Side Effects (2004).
Governments' primary role (governing -
ie creating a framework that is in the public interest in which others can 'do things') requires
support by public servants with a great deal of knowledge about how
the 'world works' and of emerging opportunities and threats facing a
community that might require changes in how it is 'governed' in the
public interest.
Governments' secondary role involves the provision of goods and
services that are subject to such significant market failures that
they can't be undertaken in a competitive market environment. Being
'business-like' (ie operating in ways appropriate to the provision
of goods and services in a competitive environment) is not not the
key to ensuring effectiveness in either governments' primary or
secondary roles. And the structural features required for
competitive delivery of goods and services can obstruct the
cross-functional collaboration required to deal with policy issues
and goods and services that suffer serious market failures.
Also the perceived 'bureaucratic'
features of government administrations are largely a by-product of
their political accountability - as this requires responsiveness to
interest groups rather than to an organization's 'customers' (see
Why are Bureaucrats bureaucratic?,
1993). 'Business-like' skills and methods (which are suitable for
customer-responsive operations) are not the key to overcoming that
source problems in government administration either.
Similar problems arose in universities where attempts
to bias outcomes to the production of more economically beneficial outputs (eg
by the adoption of managerialist and quasi-commercial methods like those applied
to public services) contributed to a significant decline in the quantity and
quality of policy options that might have enhanced governments’ ability to
‘govern’. In the 1970s and 1980s there were many valuable policy
contributions from Australia’s universities and public services but this
contribution declined dramatically in the 1990s. In the case of
universities the problem was compounded by the widespread acceptance of
‘post-modern’ ideologies (primarily in the humanities). This involved the
assumption that claims of truth in relation to human affairs were simply a
matter of opinion – rather than providing any basis for determining what is
likely to be most effective in practice (see
A
Case for Restoring Universities,
2010)
Likewise an emphasis on private ownership and control
of infrastructure that was subject to major market failures led to difficulties
in the planning and development of infrastructure (see Problems
in the Basic PPP Model, 2002+). One of those difficulties was the loss of
the public service competencies needed to guard against abuses of such
arrangements by those who gained insider influence over political decisions for
their private benefit in ways that paralleled often-expressed concerns about the
US military-industrial complex (eg see
Brisbane’s
Transportation Monster,
2008+).
And
attempts to solve governments’ ever-rising financial / efficiency problems
through external ‘audits’ have achieved little because they were not based
on a recognition of the fundamental difference between: (a) ‘governing’ (ie
creating an environment in which others (eg businesses) can do things); and (b)
‘doing things’ (eg in a competitive market environment) - see
Reforming
State Governments: Does Queensland’s Commission of Audit Have the Answer?
(2013). The latter suggests that greater gains in terms of dealing with
budget difficulties might have been achieved by ‘governing’ better (eg by
development of a stronger economy and tax base, or by reducing the social
dysfunctions that lead to large demands on the public purse) than was achieved
by merely trying to boost efficiency in ‘doing things’ that are subject to
serious market failures.
Other growing obstacles to the
development of effective democratic political institutions were considered in
Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+).
Issues: The
latter referred to:
Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+) also suggested
possible
ways to reduce those obstacles.
The need for improving democracy is not
confined to Queensland / Australia (eg see
Restoring
The Viability of Democratic Capitalism (2014) which considers the global challenge to
democracy that is posed by rising inequality; and
Dysfunctional
Democracy (2016) which comments on the need for effective reform of
democratic institutions in an international context). For example, it seems that
China is currently seeking to create an authoritarian international order like
that by which Asia was administered from China prior to Western expansion as an
alternative to the international order built on a presumption of liberal
democratic states that has prevailed since WW2 and which is compatible with
Australia’s political and economic institutions (Creating
a New International 'Confucian' Financial and Political Order, 2009+ and
China's
Strategic Approach to its Economic and Political Problems: A Speculation, 2016). And a recent account of the US
presidential race (Sheridan G., America:
here comes the revolution, The Australian, 6/2/16) implied that
insubstantial populism is dominant across the board – and this in turn implies
a dramatic decline in the US’s domestic affairs and ability to fulfill its past
role as the leader of a liberal international order.
The emphasis that the Queensland Council
for Civil Liberties is giving to enhancing the effectiveness of democracy in
Queensland is to be applauded. I wish you success in achieving your aspirations.
John Craig
|
They Never Learn
|
They Never Learn - email sent 19/2/16
Elizabeth Colman
The Australian
Re: Corporate
Chiefs Tackle Public Service Bureaucracy, The Australian, 19/2/16
Your article dealt with yet another proposal for improving
the performance of the Australian Public Service by making it more
‘business-like’. Such proposals illustrate the lack of understanding of the
nature of ‘government’ (and the dramatic differences between what is
required for successful ‘business’ and ‘government’). That lack of
understanding has been a major (though not the only) factor in the decline in
government effectiveness in Australia in recent decades.
My
Interpretation of your article: Qantas, ANZ, Telstra and
Australia Post executives will be drafted to Australian Public Service to advise
high-level bureaucrats on making public sector management more
‘business-like’. Australian Public Service Commissioner (John Lloyd)
will consult human resource experts from the nations’ biggest companies on
performance / talent management, recruitment and termination. Mr Lloyd
also believes that unions are not contributing constructively to negotiations.
Bringing in corporate advisers was recommended in a contestability review
by Sandra McPhee – which sought a mobile workforce that could move seamlessly
between corprate Australia and the public service. Ms McPhee’s review will be
made public soon by Employment Minister (Michaelia Cash) and Finance Minister
(Mathias Cormann).
Improving
Democracy refers to major deficiencies that have been introduced into government
administration in recent decades (and also to potential solutions). One of the
perennial sources of the deficiencies that have been introduced has been the
naïve
view that ‘business-like’ methods would help governments undertake their
primarily-non-business-like functions.
There is
unfortunately nothing new about ineffectual efforts to overcome the problems
that have been introduced into government administration in Australia (see
S-L-O-W
learners, 2010).
John Craig
Response from
Experienced Public Servant - Received 20/2/16
Well said! We’ve seen it all
before....... so called corporate experts with smart techniques eg
performance management to supposedly sort out the poor old Govt and
give it a facelift......as if anyone in the Corporate Sector really
has much understanding/experience of Govt anyway! Many corporate
players when transplanted to Govt either never succeed or don’t stay
long enough! They certainly don’t have a mortgage on wisdom.....none
that I’ve seen anyway.
I think the problem is also about a lack of
quality leadership from the top by our political leaders, who don’t
understand the real purpose of Govt themselves, only party politics.
So when these so called reviews are announced, we are left with a
lot of “window-dressing” with nothing actually gained !
|
The Political Process is Not the Only Source of Political Turmoil |
The Political Process is Not the Only Source of Political Turmoil - email sent 11/6/16
Professor Peter Van Onselen,
The Australian
RE: Politics
in turmoil: it’s time to reform our broken system, The Australian,
11/6/16
Your article realistically points to the fact that
Australians are becoming disillusioned with politics and suggests that reforms
to the political system are needed to correct that problem (ie by broadening the
range of people who become involved in politics; and changing the electoral
process).
However, while systemic reforms are needed to make
Australia’s political system less dysfunctional, those reforms arguably need
to go well beyond the political system itself (eg as suggested in
Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+). There has
been a growing lack of realism in Australia’s governments (and thus a decline
in their competence) that can’t be overcome simply by changes to who is
involved in politics and how they are elected.
Structural obstacle arguably include: the growing
complexity / interconnection of the issues governments need to deal with; the
need to deal with unfamiliar cultures in an increasingly global environment; the
weakening of experience-and-research-based reality checks on policies due to the
'senior'-level politicisation of public services; a loss of realism in many academics’
contributions to policy debates associated with the spread of ‘post-modern’
ideologies; seeking electoral support on the basis of ‘populism’ (ie
promising to do what is trendy irrespective of whether it is likely to be
effective); weaknesses in evaluating Australia’s strategic interests due to
traditional dependence on allies and a lack of realistic understanding of
‘Asia’; oversimplification of policies / programs as a result of
centralization; the federal fiscal imbalances that tend to prevent effective
contributions by state / local governments; and the erosion of the individual
morality that has been the necessary foundation of Australia’s liberal
political and economic institutions.
The above document includes suggestions about the sorts of
systemic reforms that are probably needed to overcome the structural
incompetence that has come to characterise Australia’s political and
government systems (see A
Nation Building Agenda). Similar suggestions in a state
government context about the need to boost the realism of what governments deal
with and thus their competence (rather than merely changing the political
process) are in
The
Upper House Solution: A Commentary (2006).
John Craig
|
The Church of Political Correctness Threatens National Progress |
The Church of Political Correctness Threatens National Progress -
email sent 22/6/16
Michael Sexton
Solicitor General, NSW
RE: The
Church of Political Correctness Controls National Discourse’, The
Australian, 3/6/16
Your article highlighted the increasing / stifling
influence of the ‘political correctness class’ (PCC) in Australia’s
institutions, and their similarities to a religious movement. You also
raised the question of how the PCC came to capture so many institutions.
My
Interpretation of your article: The
politically correct class (PCC) in Australia is like an evangelical religious
movement - and this has perhaps arisen as traditional Protestant church groups
have seen memberships decline. Some people want to be in groups with coherent
beliefs which they want to spread to others. While their opinions may be valid,
the PCC is distinguished by not wanting to debate them. Anyone who disagrees is
seen to be evil and to deserve suppression. The PCC is small in number but
influential because it dominates large sections of the media, universities,
legal professions, bureaucracies and some large corporations. Anyone in those
bodies who expresses different opinions will have limited career prospects. The
PCC came to capture these organisations from the early 1980s perhaps because of
huge expansion of universities and introduction of PCC material into schools at
that time. Australia is worse than UK and US in stifling public debate on
social and political questions. This is difficult to correct because juniors
soon realize what they are expected to believe - so the system is
self-perpetuating. There are still contrary voices - but they need to have
established positions to be immune from persecution.
I should like to suggest three factors that may have
contributed to the rise of the ‘political correctness’ problem.
First the complexity
of the issues that governments have to deal with has been growing. Gaining
proper understanding thus more and more requires considering problems from
different perspectives and taking account of many different cause-effect
relationships to assess which is most significant. However those with pre-formed
opinions tend to see only the evidence that points to the solution that they
already ‘know’ to be correct. [In the philosophy of science a similar
phenomenon is referred to as the ‘theory dependence of observations’]. Those
with pre-formed opinions and established political positions can avoid the need
to consider other points of view by simply criticising, ignoring, abusing or
otherwise punishing those who raise complexities they don’t want to consider.
[Once again this has parallels with problems recognised in the philosophy of
science – ie the difficulties of achieving fundamental ‘paradigm shifts’
in science]. ‘Conservatives’ are traditionally characterised by having
pre-determined points of view – and being unwilling to consider other points
of view. However now those who advocate what they hope to be ‘progressive’
policies are also doing so.
Second the growing
influence of post-modern
ideologies in the humanities’ faculties of Western universities
probably explains why those with what they hope are ‘progressive’ policies
now refuse to consider others’ point of view. Post-modernism is the notion
that claims of ‘truth’ are primarily a reflection of individual or cultural
preferences and have political implications because they tend to reflect the
world-view of established elites. Post-modernism is arguably a result of
recognition of the complexity that characterises social and political affairs.
However it is also an over-reaction
to that complexity – because it ignores the fact that some / many conventional
assertions about ‘truth’ are likely to be reasonable, if only approximate,
reflections of reality. Post-modernism is a form of philosophical ‘idealism’
(ie the view that ideas determine reality) as compared with ‘realism’ (ie
the notion that ideas should reflect reality). If those who are in, or have
graduated to influential positions from, a post-modern-oriented humanities’
faculty subscribe to philosophical ‘idealism’ (ie assume that ideas
primarily determine reality rather than the other way around) then they could
see ‘political correctness’ (ie promulgating hopefully-progressive ideas and
preventing consideration of alternatives) as an effective way to change the
world. However that assumption is unlikely to be realistic.
Third the 1974-1976 Royal
Commission into Australian Government Administration may have been a
factor in the rise of ‘political correctness’. Its primary conclusion was that
a lack of responsiveness by public servants led to the difficulties that the 1972-75 Whitlam Government had had in implementing its
version of the Great
Society agenda in the US in 1964-65. The latter had
been well-intended but often-simplistic - because unintended consequences
included ultimately unaffordable budgetary demands and perpetuating disadvantage
through welfare dependency [1,
2,
3,
4]. Wilinski's
theory about the need for a ruthless approach to public sector 'reform', which
was ultimately-widely-adopted in the 1980s, was apparently based on the RCAGA's
conclusion .
The consequence of seeing public servants as the problem was that subsequent
‘reform’ of government administrations in Australia (especially ‘reform’
by ALP administrations) emphasised increasing their responsiveness by
effectively politicising public services (ie ensuring that they were dominated
either by sympathisers or by ‘yes men’ and thereby
purging much of their intellectual capital) – see The
Decay of Australian Public Administration (2002). And later
non-ALP administrations also came to favour the political advantages of top-level public
service politicisation – though this had massive adverse implications for the
competence of governments (eg see
The
Growing Case for Professionalism, 2001+). I observed at first hand such a
‘reform’ process by Queensland’s 1989-95 Goss Government (see
Towards
Good Government in Queensland, 1995). The ‘reform’ process (which
largely replicated
that of Victoria’s 1982-90 Cain Government even though the latter had had
disastrous consequences) had all the characteristics that your article ascribed
to a ‘political correctness’ movement. ‘Reformers’ thought they knew all
the answers (though they tended to be inexperienced; technically out-of-date;
and intent on punishing scapegoats for past problems). No one but sympathisers
and yes-men could gain ‘senior’ positions and
nothing
could be debated or questioned on a professional basis.
I should also like to draw your attention to some
other
observers’ comments on the ‘political correctness’ phenomenon. Amongst
other points these refer to:
- A parallel between political correctness in the Australian context
and the way in which communal pressure to enforce religious-legalists’
interpretation of what Islam requires has stifled progress in Muslim majority
states; and
- The effect that stifling discussion of controversial social and
political issues may have on encouraging the emergence of political extremism.
‘Political correctness’ is however only one of the ways
in which Australians’ liberty is being constrained (see Restraining
Liberty) and thereby creating obstacles to the continued achievement of
social, economic and political progress through the rational / analytical
methods of problem solving that can be effective only where individuals are not
coerced to conform to the opinions of the self-righteous and narrow-minded (see
Erosion
of the Moral Foundations of Australia’s Liberal Institutions).
Note added later: Some
examples of the obstacles to progress that can be created by the
'faith-based beliefs' that
political correctness always reflects to some degree are illustrated by:
Assessing the Implications of Pauline
Hanson's One Nation (1998);
Complexities in the Refugee
Problem (2001);
UN Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous
Peoples: Perpetuating Disadvantage? (2007);
Finding the Truth on Climate Change
(2007);
Queensland's Preference for Economic Futility (2016);
Federal Government 'Dragging the Chain' on Reform of Safe Schools
Program (2016); and
Should Australia's Political Leaders be
'Marketing' Islam? (2016). It
can also be noted that something like 50% of the material published
in scientific journals
was suggested
in 2015 to be 'untrue' because of both the difficulty of getting
reliable results and 'a preference for pursuing fashionable trends
of dubious importance'.
In order to reduce
the ‘political correctness’ problem it would seem desirable to encourage:
(a) freedom
of speech; (b) attention
to the actual substance of complex issues about which there are political
disagreements – rather than calling opponents names; and (c) strengthening the
foundations of Australia’s liberal institutions (eg as outlined in
A
Nation Building Agenda) with particular reference to
restoring
professionalism in public services and realism
in university humanities’ faculties. Public services and academia can be
catalysts for comprehensive analytical evaluation of complex political issues
(and thus suppress ‘politically correct’ name-callers
and the political naivety and potential extremism they provoke). But they can’t /
won’t do this when they themselves are effectively politicised.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations
John Craig
|
What Then? A Government of National Unity? |
What Then? A Government of National Unity? - email sent 4/7/16
Tim Colebatch,
c/- Inside Story
In A
Long Campaign, A long Wait .. and Then What? (Inside Story, 3/6/16) you
suggested, in relation to Australia's recent
yet-undecided federal election, that some sort of coalition government arrangement was likely to be
the ‘then what’.
My suspicion is that Australia
is likely to face a debt crisis fairly soon which will force the political
system to become a lot more realistic. It might even result in the need for a
government of national unity.
At the moment we have one major
party that says Australia needs to get its economic act together – but has no
real idea how to do this in practice (eg see
here,
here
and here).
The other is committed to increasing spending on social programs. Neither is
confronting Australia’s potential ‘national’ debt crisis.
The
likely crisis (see Don't
Overlook Australia's Risk of a 'National' Credit Crisis) has its origins in:
- the dependence that domestic growth
has had on rapidly increasing ‘national’ debt (many times faster than GDP
increases) to levels (240% of GDP) that external observers believe could be
hazardous and damage the banking system because of banks’ exposure to real
estate whose value critically depends on large continuing international capital
inflows and rapidly rising national debts. ‘Government’ debt is a less
immediate threat – though its rapid rise increases risks
(especially if political instability makes
Australia ungovernable and thus leads to the threatened loss of
'governments' AAA credit rating and market attention to 'national'
debt levels);
- the potential debt crisis 1980s in
Australia’s biggest export market, China – where national debt
seems
to be rising 40% of GDP pa (ie about 6 times faster than GDP increases) from its
currently-hazardous 280% of GDP. China had been
replicating Japan's creation of huge amounts of credit with little
regard for return on, or return of, capital that led to its
late-1980's financial crisis. Escalating credit
in China is now apparently being
focused, in desperation, on creating speculative financial markets
in the hope of thereby reducing national
bad debts as China’s
regime has lost its former enthusiasm for maintaining growth by industrial /
property / infrastructure over-investment;
- High and potentially unsustainable
public and private debt levels everywhere else
because global growth has had to be
sustained for decades by reducing interest rates and quantitative
easing; and
- growing understanding that low
interest rates / quantitative easing can’t solve the problem. They have in
fact been a factor in causing deflationary demand
deficits by distorting savings and investment practices - as well as giving rise to social
inequality (as rising asset values make the rich
richer while 'real economies' and household incomes stagnate) and
thus ultimately to political instability.
A government of national unity
(if an unlikely majority ALP administration doesn’t eventuate anyway) could be
useful because the cuts to public spending that recovery will probably require
would be politically feasible if the ALP is a party to the process because (as
was the case for the socialist administration in Greece) they so obviously would
not want to do it.
The core of a possible agenda
for a government of national unity is speculated in
Alternatives
to Monetary Policy. In brief the latter suggested an emphasis on: (a)
increasing governments’ administrative competence; (b) reliance on strategic
information, rather than monetary policy or government spending, to drive
economic growth; and (c) attention to the ‘clash of civilizations’ issues
that first created chronic financial instabilities and obstacles to sustainable
global growth.
John Craig
|
What Might the 'Fifth Estate' Best Do? |
What Might the 'Fifth Estate' Best Do?
In late 2016 questions were asked about what the 'Fifth Estate' could best do
to improve Australia's current position. Core facts to consider are that someone
else has to: (a) do the groundwork that the ‘Fifth Estate’ draws together and
publicizes; and (b) turn informed public debates into public policies and
programs.
One
problem in recent years has been that the quality of that groundwork has been very poor –
because of: (a) institutional weaknesses (ie in civil institutions such as
universities and associations and in public services); and (b) the rise of
'political correctness' as a way of avoiding the need to deal with hard issues.
Some observations
about the institutional weaknesses are in
The
Upper House Solution: A Commentary (2006) and
Playing
Political Games When Major Reforms are Needed (2016). The former pointed to:
- problems in civil institutions that have arisen (for example)
from Australia’s ‘lucky country’ status. This makes (eg business / union)
association members more interested in maximizing the share they can get of
natural wealth either directly or by lobbying governments than iby contributing
to an understanding of how the community as a whole might do better. New
policies in Australia have long tended to come from outside (eg from OECD, US,
UK) rather than from domestic sources and been first identified by federal
government (because of its international connections) and only become recognised
publically and thus politically acceptable about 10-15 years later – ie well
after they were ‘state of art’ elsewhere. When the present writer was involved in strategic
policy R&D in the 1970s and 1980s this was glaringly obvious. About 20 years from the mid-1980s
was spent lobbying business associations in Queensland
to do more than put a ‘pro-business’ spin on current policies. This was a waste
of time as they were committed to just putting a pro-business spin
on whatever policy ideas were trendy. In late 2016 someone starting wondering
whether the Business Council of Australia should do more than that (see
What
will BCA’s choice of a new leader say about its direction?, 15/10/16).
This was being considered apparently because of the virtual complete absence
of any serious economic policy agenda by either side before the recent federal
election – in the face of a situation where there is a desperate need for vast
improvements (see
Playing
Political Games).
- Problems in public services as service professionals had
traditionally been relied on to come up with constructive policy options. As
Playing
Political Games also pointed out, public services almost ceased to be
able to this from the late 1980s because ‘reform’ agendas were put in place
to make public services more ‘responsive’ – which mainly meant that that
they came to be dominated by cronies and ‘yes men’. In the late 1990s
the present writer had a brief role in the Queensland Premier’s Department and was involved
with an inter-departmental group that was looking at the government’s ability
to plan (the so-called ‘Preparing for the Future’ project). The consensus by
senior agency staff was that they needed to set up systematic processes to
assemble and disseminate strategic information relevant to the future of
whatever functions that they were responsible for – because the absence of
such intelligence severely limited their performance. However the powers that be
did not want to know.
A general observation about the 'political correctness' problem is in
The Church of Political Correctness Threatens National
Progress. This suggests that: (a) attacking skeptics (rather than
debating the substance of issues) has increasingly become a common tactic in
advocating what are hoped to be 'progressive policies; and that: (b) the
solution must be to refuse to allow debate about difficult issues to be
obstructed that way.
If the Fifth Estate is to make a real difference it probably needs to
look at how to overcome institutional obstacles (ie the relative lack of
heavyweight sources) and the retreat into political correctness.
One way to achieve this over a number of years would be by seeking
out and publicizing the efforts (and competing conclusions) of those in civil institutions or government
agencies whose jobs involve: (a) systematically assembling strategic
intelligence about some issue; and / or (b) drawing conclusions about the
practical implications of such intelligence. The result should be a
gradual increase in the ‘meat’ in the public policy and economic debates that the Fifth
Estate covers and thus in its ability to contribute to constructively 'changing the world'.
However there is also a need to recognise the limits of informed
public debates in terms in terms of what is needed to generate effective
public policies.
Public comment reflects: (a) a combination of historical and emergent
information; and (b) diverse viewpoints all of which are usually right
in some ways and wrong in others.
It is thus a great basis for political debate but is not
sufficient to ensure constructive outcomes.
Firstly there are limits to what governments can do because political
involvement in dealing with social, economic or environmental challenges
will tend to distort responses to those challenges (eg create dependence
on public finance in an environment in which this may be constrained).
Apolitical processes of stimulating systemic responses need to be given
more emphasis (eg as suggested in an economic context in
A Case for Innovative Economic
Leadership, 2009).
Secondly public debate is always about 10-15 years behind current
expert understandings and the political system has no way in itself to
resolve differences in viewpoint (other than through the shouting
matches that increasingly characterise Australia's political
system). There was real value in the ability that a professional /
experienced public service used to have to
complement the diverse / potentially-out-of-date perspectives in the political
system with an integrated perspective (through consultation /
committees) that was built on practical experience.
Finally there is a problem related to Australia’s historical
‘branch’ office / dependent status on UK / US leadership – namely the
lack of domestic strategic understanding (ie an in-depth awareness of
what is happening in the external environment and thus what will be the
best way to be positioned for the likely future environment). In debates
about the Iraq war decision it was
pointed out that Australia’s Defence system has been very good at
tactical issues but lacks strategic competencies. Recognition of this
limitation may lead to better Defence policy in future. However this
problem is not been limited to Defence. In the 1980s the present writer
was associated with many public servants who tried to promote better
economic strategies. Subsequently they were all forced to retreat into
sinecures as technical experts (ie into dealing with ‘tactical’ rather
than 'strategic' issues) which are worthless if there is no competent
strategic judgment anywhere.
|
Problems with a 'Post-truth' World |
Problems with a 'Post-truth' World - email sent 30/11/16
Professor Rob Brooks,
University of NSW
Re: How
tribal thinking has left us in a post-truth world, The Conversation, 29/11/16
There is no doubt that what you refer to as a
‘post-truth’ world leads to problems. Overly simplistic public opinion which
becomes the basis of ‘populist’ official policy can lead to practical
failures (eg consider Will
Donald Trump's Economic Agenda Make America and the World Great? ).
However (as the latter argues) the populist / ‘post
truth’ / impractical public policy, which has emerged as a result of a
‘crisis of public confidence in expertise, knowledge and evidence’, is not
entirely unjustified. There have, for example, been real problems in what
economic ‘experts’ have been proclaiming because of the mainstream economic
view that economics should strive to be a ’real (ie deterministic) science’
like physics – and thus a failure to perceive that new deterministic
relationships can be created in social and economic systems (see
Fixing
Economics).
There have been similar problems in non-economic fields
where ‘experts’ have presumed that they were defending ‘truth’ whereas
what they were doing at times was defending uncertain assumptions by refusing to
discuss the possibility that some of their core assumptions might be inadequate
– a stance that was hardly helpful (see The
Church of Political Correctness Threatens National Progress) .
I noted your observations about the refusal of those who
believe that Darwinian natural selection is a sufficient explanation of
evolution to consider any other possibility. There is case for taking a broader
view (see Problems
in an Internally Deterministic Scientific Worldview ). Just as
mainstream economists have created economic problems by refusing to consider the
possibility of ‘creation’ (ie intentionally changing causal relationships in
economic systems), this may also be a problem in the world of mainstream natural
science.
John Craig
|
Managing a Complex World |
Managing a Complex World - email sent 15/12/16
Professor David Green,
Monash University
Re: Simple
thinking in a complex world is a recipe for disaster, The Conversation,
14/12/16
Your article was extremely constructive in highlighting the
very real challenge that complexity poses to human understanding – and the
dangers of overly-simplistic ideas / mental ‘models’. While there is little
doubt about those limitations (eg see Populism
As a Backlash Against Incomprehensible Complexity), I should like to submit
for your consideration that: (a) relatively simple understandings can be
effective providing they are used in appropriate institutional contexts; and (b)
those who seek to better understand complexity need to recognise the limitations
that they also face.
My
Interpretation of your article: Ants are simple creatures
and live by simple rules. For all humans’ sophistication they also react to a
complex world in simple ways. The result can be that our actions have unintended
side-effects. Our brains are bombarded with more information than we can
progress – and there are limits to our memories. We cope with complexity by
filtering out details and develop recipes for dealing with common situations. We
deal with complexity by removing / hiding it. We simplify complex decision
making using received wisdom / rules of thumb. Organisations manage complexity
through hierarchical divisions. We use constraints (laws / road rules /
commercial standards) to limit harmful interactions. This works as long as the
world behaves as we expect – but influences that are not considered can cause
mental models to fail. New technologies can have this effect. We find it
easier to rely on others to deal with complex problems (eg mentors / experts/
politicians). However their models are just as susceptible as everyone else’s.
Our inability to fathom complexity lead to belief that any worthwhile solution
must be simple (and this can explain mistrust of science today). Changes
introduce complexity into people’s lives and some retreat into denial –
hoping for an unchanged future. In the era of post-truth and pseudo science
there is a need to avoid just dismissing uncomfortable facts. Complexity arises
from the interaction of things – and ignoring the wider context is perilous.
Western societies have arguably been able to achieve
centuries of relatively rapid progress, because having a liberal social
environment allowed liberal economic and political institutions to be
created. Such institutions broke issues into manageable ‘bits’ (eg via
a rule of law, profit oriented market economies and secular democratic states)
and this allowed mental ‘models’ to be reasonably reliable for practical
problems solving despite the limitations that complexity places on rationality
and analysis that your article mentioned (see
Cultural
Foundations of Western Progress: The Realm of the Rational / Responsible
Individual (2001+).
However in recent decades the reliability of those
institutions has been eroding (eg see Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building, 2003+ and
Fixing
Economics, 2012).
Why: Governance has
become less effective because of: increased complexity; exposure to unfamiliar
cultures due to globalization; politicisation that narrowed understanding;
‘post-modern’ ideologies in humanities faculties that discouraged
understanding; populism which accepted trendy ideas irrespective of their
practicality; and erosion of the moral foundations of liberal social
environments and secular states).
Economics has become less effective
because a foundational desire to understand economic systems (ie for economics
to be a ‘real science’ like physics) has been incompatible with
systematically changing them (and thus changing what would be ‘understood’).
Some speculations about how these problems might be reduced
are in:
More
Competent Support to Parliament (2006) – in relation to a state
administration; A
Nation Building Agenda (2008) – which addressed institutional reforms more
generally; and What
Might the 'Fifth Estate' Best Do? (2016).
Your article reasonably noted that introducing unexpected
and unfamiliar complexities can potentially render traditional ‘wisdom’
unreliable – so that people who might like things the way they were in the
past (ie conservatives) need to recognise the need to be flexible. However the
same applies to those who might prefer things to be the way they think that they
should be in the future (ie progressives) – eg see The
Church of Political Correctness Threatens National Progress (2016) and
Scientific
Debate on Climate Change (2016). As the latter notes, even what can be known
through science is limited – so ‘progressive’ experts need to be as
flexible in their thinking as their ‘conservative’ counterparts.
It can also be noted that a substantial part of humanity
does not traditionally adhere to the notion that mental ‘models’ are
reliable and has developed alternative methods for practical problem solving (eg
see East
Asia: The Realm of the Autocratic and Intuitive Ethnic Hierarchy?). However
that is another story – and those worldviews also contain limitations at least
equal to, though different from, those your article mentioned.
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations
John Craig
|
A Queensland View of 'The Plight of Australia' |
A Queensland View of 'The Plight of Australia' - email sent 22/12/16
John Edwards
Lowy Institute
Re: The
Plight of the Right, Inside Story, 5/12/16 (and William
Coleman’s response ‘The
Plight of Australia’, Inside Story, 19/12/16)
On the basis of many years involvement in trying to
encourage Queensland (and Australia to some extent) to ‘move on’
economically, I should like to try to add value to the debate reflected in your
comments.
Your article suggests that a perception that Australia has
difficulty in ‘moving on’ (ie doing things much differently from the way
they have always been done) was the main theme of the book that William Coleman
edited (Only
in Australia: The History, Politics, and Economics of Australian Exceptionalism).
His recent article said much the same thing in a different way:
“Coleman’s central claim is that
“Australia is the country that won’t move on, which is stuck in its
way.” (from Plight
of the Right).
“….
the inertial position is favoured by myself, and probably by most of the
book’s contributors. What characterises Australian policy history, I say, is
not the agile shift of adaptation, but rigidity. Change is more a matter of form
than substance; and an Australian Way endures today in spite of the changes in
economic policy since the 1970s.” (from Plight
of Australia)
Your article maintained that Australia has done well
recently in adapting (its economy for example) to changing circumstances whereas the
contributors to the book William Coleman edited apparently tended to suggest
that it has not. Some reasons that I suspect that the contributors to William
Colman’s book are more accurate are outlined in
Defects
in Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes (2000).
In an earlier response to your article I drew attention to
Playing
Political Games When Major Reforms are Needed and
Broken
Governance and Ineffectual Economic Strategy: Two Sides of the Same Coin?.
These suggested that Australia has to do something other than continue with
‘business as usual’ to now avoid a serious economic problem.
More
recent suggestions about why this is so are in
Appalling
Queensland Governments. This noted both: (a) the continued use in
Queensland (with which I was most familiar) of traditional
politically-rather-then-market-driven tactics in attempts to create the more
knowledge based economy that was recognised to be needed in the 1980s; and (b)
the need to do more (and the virtual complete absence
of the apolitical (especially business) leadership needed to achieve
this). There is an emerging risk of debt crises in both
Australia
and its largest export market (China) and a consequent need to ensure that
investment in future makes a much greater contribution to increasing GDP
(and thus to reducing Australia's hazardously
high debt / GDP ratio) than
has come to be the case. It also suggested that strategies that seek to
raise productivity and competitiveness by market liberalization (which was the
basis of economic reforms in the 1980s and 1990s) are not adequate in themselves
to achieve this – and that there are better alternatives.
In relation to the broader question of whether or not
Australia has structural difficulties in adapting to its economic and other
challenges, I have to again suggest that William Coleman’s view seems more
accurate.
I was employed for over 25 years in Queensland’s most
senior public service group (Coordinator General’s Department / Office) in a
strategic policy R&D role (ie identifying strategic opportunities /
challenges facing Queensland) - see CV.
This started with an official desire the early 1970s to modernise
Queensland’s system of government. This worked until the late 1970s when
political tolerance disappeared as the ‘resource curse’ (ie easy gains by
exploiting natural resources) triumphed. However I was encouraged by senior
public servants to continue doing what I had been doing – until this became
impossible under a new administration which believed that it was the
‘solution’ to Queensland’s difficulties in ‘moving on’ rather than
another (inexperienced and out-of-date) ‘symptom’. I continued advocating
institutional reforms independently (see About
CPDS)
.
A broad overview of what I suspect has been the historical
source of Queensland’s problem in seriously developing a productive modern
economy is in Smart
State: A Broader History. This referred to: (a) the effect of
the ‘resources
curse’ (ie the adverse effects that rich resources often have on the
quality of economic leadership available to a community from its political /
business leaders – because easy benefits come from exploiting natural
resources rather than developing community economic competencies);
(b) an unwillingness in the general community (eg in
business) to provide leadership in achieving economic changes that could not be
successful if politically driven; (c) Australia
having inherited government institutions from the UK without much ability within
the general community to understand why those institutions took the form they
did and thus how they might successfully / safely be
changed; and (d) Australia’s dependence on the UK / US / OECD for policy
initiatives. ‘Australia’ as a whole was different (ie suffered these
limitations less than Queensland) but exhibited those symptoms to some degree.
There has thus been some collective inability to ‘move on’ in ways
appropriate to a changing environment.
My early role involved scanning the world for
‘strategic’ (ie important emerging) trends. Doing so showed that Queensland
/ Australia seemed to suffer a 10-15 year lag in adapting. Policy innovation
elsewhere tended to be copied after a process involving: (a) analysis of recent
trends elsewhere by (say) OECD; (b) importing the trends through the federal
government because of its international links; and (c) passing the trends down
through hierarchical government machinery. The capacity of civil
institutions and government agencies to directly interface with international
sources of such trends or to pursue realistic domestic policy innovation was
limited – and the capacity of the general community (and their elected
representatives in particular) to understand the issues if they did so was even
more limited (because of the lack of an informed local view of how society,
economy and government should work). However the views of external
‘experts’ were taken as gospel (when they trickled through the process
outlined above) even if they were not as relevant locally as they had been seen
to be elsewhere or if they were not working adequately elsewhere.
It has been drawn to the present writer's attention
that:
- Western Australia small businesses tend to
rely on external 'experts' and have little capacity to develop
options for improvement internally. This paralleled the present
writer's experience (see above) in trying to encourage Queensland
business to consider innovative approach to economic development;
- policy initiatives adopted by one
state tend to be copied by others without checking to see whether
they have worked. Copying Victoria's early 1980s approach to public
sector reform in Queensland from the late 1980s, which the present
writer observed at close hand, illustrated that problem.
Victoria's methods had already proven
disastrous when they were
uncritically copied up north despite public service warnings (based
on Queensland's past experience) about the damage they would do ;
- the US model that was the basis of
Australia's NAPLAN methods for monitoring student performance have
reportedly been abandoned in the US on the grounds that they worsen
educational performance (a claim that the present writer can't
assess) [1].
They continue to be used in Australia in an environment in which
there is concern about deteriorating educational performance. A case
for not doing so now seems to rely mainly on the fact that those
methods were abandoned in the US.
The virtual absence now of 'authoritative' policy
directions from offshore that can be implemented locally creates a major problem
for Australia given continued weaknesses in domestic institutions.
Somewhat-dated suggestions about how the limits on
(respectively} Australia’s / Queensland’s ability to ‘move on’ sensibly
in relation to emerging challenges / opportunities were in
Australia's
Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+) and
Curing
Queensland’s Myopia (2011). The former referred (for example) to:
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations
John Craig
|
An Increasingly Unhappy Australia Didn't Start with Rudd in 2007 |
|
Energy Crisis: The Real Problem is Machinery of Government Changes
That Made Long Term Planning Impossible |
Energy Crisis: The Real Problem is Machinery of Government Changes That Made Long Term Planning Impossible - email sent 21/3/17
Alan Pears,
RMIT University
RE: Gas
crisis? Energy crisis? The real problem is lack of long-term planning, The
Conversation, 20/3/17
Your article provided a reasonable outline of Australia’s
energy-related crisis – and suggested that a lack of planning was the problem.
However there is a need to look at the reasons that planning was ineffectual.
They arguably include: (a) politicising public administration; and (b)
privatising the electricity supply industry, and then adopting renewable-energy
requirements that escalated the market failures affecting that industry.
My
Interpretation of your article: Australia
has an energy crisis partly due to a gas crisis and this has led to a political
crisis. Energy costs matter more than energy prices (ie using less at high
prices could cost less). There are many factors involved in energy. Short term
solutions to deal with part of the problem could create long term problems. For
electricity there is a need to: avoid blackouts; limit prices / costs; and adopt
solutions with low greenhouse emissions. For gas there is a need to supply local
demand and allow large consumers to negotiate favourable prices. More gas
needs to be allocated to local demand – as increasing gas usage overall would
just add to overall climate problems. Peak gas and electricity markets are
entangled. Most expensive electricity generator (eg involving gas) sets prices
in periods of peak demand, then other generators make windfall profits. Thus we
must either ensure that gas generators don’t set the price or that they charge
reasonable prices. Demand management and energy storage are short term fixes for
high peak prices. Encouraging some users to use less at peak periods frees up
electricity or gas, so prices do not rise as much. Policymakers have not
arranged effective methods for encourage reduced demand. Energy storage can be
introduced fairly quickly (eg batteries / gas storage). Proposals for ‘pumped
hydro’ at Snowy would have similar effect – though it would take years to
implement. South Australia’s plan for short term changes is better that the
federal government’s Snowy option. In the long term it is necessary to slash
carbon emissions. There are affordable long term solutions. The IEA and some
Australian analysts (ClimateWorks and Beyond Zero Emissions) see energy
efficiency improvements as key strategy. Cheap gas and electricity could allow
Australian business, industry, households to lift efficiency. It is also
possible to shift from fossil gas to biogas, solar thermal and high energy
renewable electricity technologies. Renewable energy can supply the rest of our
needs – and is now cheaper than traditional options. But renewable energy
needs to be supplemented with energy storage and smart demand management. The
crisis is more political than practical. Politicians need to free
themselves from being trapped in the past and propping up powerful incumbent
industries.
Crises have been a major feature of Australian public administration in
recent decades. There is nothing unique about the systemic failure that are now
seen in energy supplies. Some suggestions about the cause of those problems were
outlined in
Decay
of Australian Public Administration
(2002+). This emphasised the adverse effects of: (a) appointing senior
officials who would be ‘politically responsive’ rather than experienced
professionals who could (and would) provide a reality check on poor policy
options; and (b) emphasisng ‘business-like’ methods to improve efficiency in
undertaking governments’ primarily non-business-like operational functions.
Towards
a Professional Public Service referred to previous documents on my web-site
about this, while The
Growing Case for Professionalism
(2001+) identified many resulting dysfunctions.
The adverse effects of politicising and
‘commercializing’ governments in relation to the planning and development of
infrastructure were suggested in
Infrastructure
Constraints on Australia’s Economy (2005). This referred to: (a) apparent
reasons for the failures that had arisen in developing infrastructure in
Queensland – a state with which the present writer is most familiar; (b)
problems resulting from privatising functions subject to serious market
failures; (c) emphasis on infrastructure deficiencies as the main constraint on
Australia’s economy; (d) financial constraints on infrastructure spending in
the absence of real progress in developing the productivity of Australia’s
economy and thus governments’ tax base; and (e) federal government efforts to
micro-manage infrastructure development.
Your article highlighted the many complexities that constitute ‘market
failures’ in the provision of electricity services (ie the inability of purely
commercial (ie profit-focused) undertakings to manage non-commercial
relationships with other services and policy issues). Functions subject to
major market failures are best not managed through ‘commercial’ machinery (eg
because: (a) such systems may need to be managed as a whole rather than a
separate undertakings; and (b) a need for intense regulatory supervision can
impose costs that offset any efficiency gains from ‘private’ production –
see About
Private Public Partnerships, 2002). Moreover shifting such functions to the private sector may
result in inadequate technical competence remaining in the public sector to deal
with their ‘public affairs’ implications.
The search for energy solutions with low greenhouse emissions
dramatically compounded the moderate market failures that were intrinsic in
Australia’s energy systems. However, because those energy systems involved
only ‘commercial’ undertakings, there were no government organisations with
the technical knowledge and policy oversight needed to highlight the possible
consequences of requiring low greenhouse emissions.
It may be even
more significant that low greenhouse emissions were required as an absolute
political priority for Australia’s future energy options even though the
scientific basis for this has not yet been settled. The mandate and perspective
of the International Panel for Climate Change has been too narrow to do so (eg
consider
Former
President Of Greenpeace Scientifically Rips Climate Change To Shreds, 2015; and
the present writer’s similar contention in
Finding
the Truth on Climate Change, 2007).
John Craig
|
The Inadequacies of Mr Abbott's Progressive Proposals |
The Inadequacies of Mr Abbott's Progressive Proposals - email sent 30/3/17
Peter Bowden
Re: Tony
Abbott defines the new conservatism – Online Opinion, 20/3/2017
I was interested to see your criticism of Tony Abbott’s
five point plan (ie cut RET / immigration / official bullying / spending and
reform senate) because, while I have no involvement with any political faction and Mr
Abbott’s proposals seem simplistic, I suspect that they might be
‘progressive’ (in the sense that they are at least trying to deal with
issues that need attention) rather than ‘conservative’.
First, there are reasons to believe that mainstream
climate science (on which the RET is based) needs to be reviewed (see
Former
President of Greenpeace Scientifically Rips Climate Change to Shreds, 2015
and my earlier similar argument Finding
the Truth on Climate Change, 2007). This does not mean that scrapping RET is
justified (any more than eliminating climate change related policies is
justified in the US) – but it does point to growing recognition that
mainstream climate science has been overly simplistic and needs review from a
less one-sided viewpoint.
Second, cutting immigration is probably the best way
to deal with housing affordability – because there are significant other
issues involved, namely defects in the machinery used for planning urban
development and providing infrastructure. The latter need to be fixed – and
while these are being fixed (which will take quite some time) it would be highly
desirable to reduce the pressure on them from rapid urban population growth (see
Reducing
Immigration Would Not Just Solve the Housing Affordability Problem and
Bring
Infrastructure into the 21st Century: Some Suggestions).
Third, while eliminating the Human Rights Commission
would be an overkill, there have been serious obstacles to progress in important
areas associated with the way in which Section 18C has been expressed and
implemented (see Exposing
the Source of Islamist Radicalization and the following interchange with Dr
Andrew Jakubowicz).
Fourth, there is a desperate need to bring
government spending and revenue into balance. Australia faces a potential debt
crisis because of its very high national debt to GDP ratio (see
Australia's
Risk of Financial / Banking Crises as Growth is Driven by Rapidly Rising and
Often Misdirected Debt). The rapid rise in government debts (because
of spending well in excess of revenue) matters because it will potentially
result in a loss of the federal government’s AAA credit rating and thus the
credibility of any government guarantees in terms of providing support (eg to
major financial institutions) in the event of a national debt crisis. The
imbalance between federal government revenue and spending seems to have arisen
by fully committing (to tax cuts and social transfers) the revenue earned at the
top of a mining investment boom – without considering that the boom might not
last forever (see The
Long Term Impact of the GFC). The fact that spending and revenue
need to be brought into balance does not necessarily imply that spending must be
cut – because there are options to boost revenues by strengthening
governments’ tax bases (as suggested in
Bring
Infrastructure into the 21st Century: Some Suggestions).
Fifth, there is a desperate need (for reasons also
suggested in Bring
Infrastructure into the 21st Century: Some Suggestions) to reform
Australia’s machinery of government to make it less unworkable. Merely
reforming the Senate would be inadequate – but that proposal is at least
pointing towards the need for machinery of government reform.
John Craig
|
Reform Proposals Need Deeper Analysis
|
Reform Proposals Need Deeper Analysis - email sent 14/5/17
Dr David Swanton,
Ethical Rights and
Exit International, c/- Editor, Online
Opinion.
Re: An
Australian should be Australia’s head of state, Online Opinion,
3/5/17
Your article raised many questions about Australia’s head
of state – while mentioning other possible reforms in passing. I should like
to submit that the ‘head of state’ issue (and others) are not as simple as
you implied. Australia’s political process has been weakening because problems
/ opportunities have increasingly been being identified without anyone having
any clear idea about how to successfully address them (see
On
Populism, 2007+). Doing more
than this is vital for real progress.
My
Interpretation of your article: Parents
hope that their children are healthy, well-educated and can realize their
dreams. In many countries (including Australia) children’s aspirations are
limited – as they can never be head of state. Australia is a representative
democracy and constitutional monarchy whose head of state is the Queen of
Australia, who is also Queen of UK and elsewhere. UK monarchy is class-based
system of institutionalised nepotism that discriminates on the basis of
religion, gender, age and family (descent). Australia’s head of state should
be appointed or selected on the basis of merit. Religious bias was illustrated
by the Queens’s reference to a time when most subjects were in Church of
England. Religion is a personal matter for individuals. This religious link to
Australia’s head of state is reflected in Australia’s constitution. The
preamble involves people humbly relying on the blessings of Almighty God. An
‘Almighty God’ is imaginary as from a scientific viewpoint there is no
evidence – and is only believed in by those indoctrinated or acculturated to
that belief system. It is ridiculous to include reference to religious figures
in a legal document. Constitutional problems would arise if the Queen changed
her religion. The British monarchy is sexist. The present Queen has done an
excellent job. An independent Australia does not need a head of state who
promotes Britain, or a non-Australian picture on its currency. The Queen’s
Australian functions are carried out by Governor Generals – but she must
appoint them. Australia’s record of constitutional reform has been poor –
but there is a need to remove religious references, recognise Australia’s
indigenous heritage and modernise the Constitution. Australia should have an
Australian head of state – who might even be a ‘first Australian’. The
Queen could initiate this process. A head of state selected from flawed
class-based system in a foreign country that discriminates on the basis of
religion, gender, age and family is not-merit-based / unacceptable. A republic
of some form is needed – and this would allow Australian children to aspire to
being head of state.
There is a reasonable case an Australian head of state. Unfortunately,
advocates have not made any serious effort to identify how this could work in
practice. Your article did not attempt to do so either. You suggested that a
head of state could be ‘selected’ or ‘elected’ on the basis of merit.
However an ‘elected’ head of state (ie one with a political agenda and
mandate of their own) would be chosen on the basis of the popularity of their
agenda – not its merit. Such a head of state would be incompatible with
Australia’s Westminster system (see Australia's
State and Territory Governments Want a 'Republic' - Whatever That Means,
2016). Government executives are drawn from the legislature. This has advantages
but also reduces the separation of powers (between legislature, executive and
judiciary) that otherwise provides a check against abuses of power. The risk of
abuse of power under a Westminster system is limited because a head of
state with no policy agenda of their own monitors / approves what the
legislature and executive do (eg by ensuring compliance with constitutional
provisions). The necessary apolitical oversight would not be available with an
‘elected’ (ie political) head of state. Countries with separately
elected presidents and executive governments are apparently more likely to
suffer instability and revolution than those that don’t. A ‘republican’
referendum was conducted in 1999 that might have resulted in a reasonable
process for ‘selecting’ an Australian head of state. However ‘republican
advocates’ (who did not seem to have considered the practical aspects of the
issue) believed that the head of state should be ‘elected’ (ie political).
Controversy about this caused the referendum to fail.
Your article
referred to another constitutional change (ie recognising Australia’s
indigenous heritage). Many groups have been struggling to work out how to do
this – so far without success. There are reasons that the problem is
challenging for reasons that most advocates of indigenous recognition
don’t want to consider – namely that culture is the primary determinant of
people’s ability to be materially successful (eg see
Recognizing
What?, 2005 and
UN
Declaration on the Rights of Indigenous Peoples: Perpetuating Disadvantage?, 2007). Throw-away remarks about ‘recognising Australia’s indigenous
heritage’ as part of a process to ‘modernise’ the constitution don’t
help in moving towards a practical and effective solution.
In relation to other matters raised in your article, it is submitted that
there are complexities that your article did not recognise. For example:
- There are many reasons Australian children can’t
achieve what they might – and their dysfunctional social, economic and
political environment seems the most serious (see
Gonski
Review: An Example of the Limitations of Government Initiatives,
2013);
- The Christian elements that are reflected in
Australia’s Constitution are non-trivial because widespread Christian
adherence is necessary as a social foundation for the liberal institutions
Australia’s Constitution provides for (eg see
Christian
Foundations of Liberal Western Institutions ,
2010 and Christianity
is the Necessary Foundation for Applying Rational Thought in Practice, 2017);
- And, as the latter also
noted, there is no scientific basis for proving your assertion that ‘Almighty
God’ is simply a product of human imaginings.
Science now increasingly requires recognition that there is ‘something’ out
there – but does not help in identifying the nature of that ‘something’
(eg parallel / intersecting universes or ‘Almighty God’);
- Australia’s
Constitution is a legal document. However a genuine ‘rule of law’ (as
compared with a ‘rule of man’ through arbitrary laws defined to suit the
purposes of social, religious and political elites) is uncommon. A real ‘rule
of law’ is arguably only possible if God’s law is accepted as a higher
source of authority (eg see comments
on the ‘rule of law’ in
Mangalwadi’s ‘The Book that Made Your World’). A real ‘rule of law’
can’t exist if human claims to be the highest ethical / religious authority
are taken seriously. And it was Christianity’s founder (Jesus of Nazareth) who
uniquely discredited such claims by human political and religious elites (see
Where
Did Religious Freedom Come From?,
2015). The alternatives to this that are being now being promoted include:
(a) the theocratic aspirations of Islamists; (b)
ascribing
the ‘mantle of heaven’
(the traditional religious basis of Emperors’ authority in East Asia) to
China’s presidents; and (c) the resistance to evaluation of their opinions by political ‘correctness’ movements
(see The Church of Political Correctness
Threatens National Progress, 2016).
Suggestions about issues where constructive changes might be made need to
be accompanied by a depth of analysis if realistic / practical proposals for
action (rather than agendas for insubstantial political populists) are to
result.
John Craig
|