Outline +
Attachments
|
Outline
Queensland has a history of adopting economic strategies which have been (and
continue to be) ineffectual in developing a productive modern economy - as
evidenced by continued low community incomes by
national standards,
relatively low per capita state product and the problems which many regions
suffer.
Queensland's 'traditional' strategy (ie that of
the 1980s) involved: facilitating major foreign investments; low taxation; and
minor amounts of 'assistance' to fill market gaps. Unfortunately it produced
poor quality growth, eg tourism and capital intensive resource operations -
which have their productivity limited by competition from low wage economies. Moreover an emphasis
on 'growth' (without concern for development) can result in activities with
large and rapidly increasing revenues and expenditures but where the difference
between these (which contributes to economic product in the form of profits /
wages / taxes) is small. And government 'assistance' to individual firms is the
opposite of, and a major obstacle to, development of the economy.
Queensland missed an opportunity to significantly
improve its 'traditional' strategy in the 1990s - partly because an ineffectual
process of public sector 'reform' eliminated the capabilities to do so
which had been emerging in the 1980s.
By the start of the 21st century, Queensland's strategy was aimed at higher
goals (eg developing a more productive economy, and an innovation capability so
as to profit from, rather than be the victim of, economic change). However to
achieve this, populist rather than realistic policies
have been adopted. Government has foolishly tried to force the pace and
direction of economic change (eg under the Smart State agenda, and by trying to
'bribe' external firms to locate in Queensland - a tactic which had lost
credibility elsewhere many years earlier because of competition from low wage
economies for the location of 'footloose' firms). In particular, the Department
of State Development seemed to see itself as having a hands-on responsibility
for developing the 'state' - rather than developing the 'economy' so that
business and the community could effectively develop the state.
There is increasing pressure for improved performance (eg
because of currency revaluation; the need for a stronger tax base to fund
public services and infrastructure expectations; the increasing importance of
exports after bursting of housing bubble in the face of a deteriorating international
trading environment and worsening export performance; infrastructure and skills
deficiencies that limit growth; the changing economic environment and greater uncertainty
associated with Asia's increased economic significance; environmental risks;
the probable need to 'reinvent' resource related industries; escalating social
dysfunctions which have economic dimensions; and international
instabilities). Simultaneously stronger competition is emerging to challenge
traditional activities (eg because of rapid development of medium technology
capabilities in Asia; global outsourcing; and a potential US Free Trade
Agreement).
Queensland's main problem in responding is the lack of adequate machinery to
cope with economic change - especially in relation to the mutual support
required between complementary elements of industry clusters. A
more effective economic strategy might involve: development of civil
institutions able to accelerate 'learning' by whole industry clusters; emphasis
on creating competitive advantages, rather than reliance on the given
comparative advantages of regional economies; public stimulus to adjustment by
economic 'losers'; increased taxation partly to slow the ongoing shift to a less economically
productive population through migration; increased concern for effective international economic and
political environments; and renewal of Queensland's Public Service on a
professional basis.
|
Evidence |
Evidence
The primary evidence of substandard economic strategies lies in outcomes, such as a Queensland per-capita gross state product (GSP) that
seems to be perpetually
about 15% below Australia's national average despite the fact that: (a)
Queensland has traditionally accounted for a large share of inward investment
into Australia; and (b) Australia's gross domestic product per capita was in long term decline by international standards. And in 2001-02,
Queensland's per-capita GSP apparently declined again relative to national averages (see
About Queensland's
Budget).
In 2003 useful gains in improving the productivity of
Queensland's economy through the effect of successful economic strategy were claimed [1], with similar
claims subsequently made regarding Australia's national economic performance (eg that there has
been a turn-around in Australia's long term decline in relative incomes) [1].
However there are many complexities which render these analyses uncertain
(see
Does Productivity Growth Confirm Smart State?, Note 3, and
Impact of Economic
Liberalism in Australia). For example, the effect over several years
of substantial devaluation of the $A on commodity exports would be to create
the impression of rapid economic and productivity growth (which would be more
significant in Queensland's more export oriented economy) - but this factor
(and many others that complicate the assessment) do not
seem to have been considered.
Moreover other evidence suggests that claims of superior performance should
be treated with caution. In particular:
- there are numerous indicators of the traditional under-development of Queensland's economy (eg
see Section 5.2 of a 1994 paper,
SEQ-2001: A Plan for an Underdeveloped Economy, and a detailed segment on
Queensland as an Under-developed
Economy);
- in the early 1990s Australia was seen to
be diversifying
into capital intensive operations (rather than knowledge intensive
functions) (Access Economics and Allen Consulting, Developing Australia's
National Competitiveness, for Business Council Summit on 'Our
Competitive Future' - 1991). Moreover encouraging such investment
(ie in 'projects') remained the focus of unsophisticated state economic
strategies in the 1990s. The problem is that capital intensive functions now
tend to face constrained productivity (due to competition
from lower wage global regions). In particular this problem beset
resource-based industries in the 1990s (see
Note 9), a sector that remains of major
economic significance;
- many marginal (rural, coastal and metropolitan) regions simply fell
behind the necessary rate of economic change in the 1990s - resulting in serious social
symptoms and political instability (See Assessing
the Implications of Pauline Hanson's One Nation). Moreover various marginal (metropolitan, rural and coastal)
regions face continuing
difficulties.
For example:
- many regions have been identified as lacking features required for future
prosperity; and local authorities concerned about such problems believe that the state
government provides little support - because the Department of State
Development was primarily concerned with
'big ticket' items [1];
-
under-employment has been widespread (due to the availability of mainly poor
quality jobs) [1]
and unemployment has been persistently high [1].
The availability of mainly poor quality jobs has been seen as a major factor
in the emergence of poverty as an intractable problem in Australia [1].
Some observers claim that a permanent under-class has emerged [1,
2]:
-
social equity was only maintained by large compensating social transfers [1];
- Queensland in particular has had a poor performance in terms of job quality (see
Employment;
Tourism)
and job numbers at times (eg see 'Budget fails grade on job creation', editorial,
Courier Mail, 20/6/01);
-
Australia's international ranking in innovation (a major factor in the
productivity of leading economies) has been in constant decline [1],
and a separation typically exists in firms between those concerned about
intellectual property and those concerned with creating competitive advantage [1]
- perhaps for reasons like those suggested in
The
Economic Futility of Backing Australia's Ability 2, and
Commentary on Smart State program.
Australia's status in this respect is not only poor with respect to OECD
economies, but is rapidly being surpassed by developments in India, China and
SE Asia [1];
-
export performance has been deteriorating [see
below];
- the sophistication of
economic policy concepts emerging either from governments or from independent
research institutions appears [to the author] either not to have improved (where it was
traditionally weak) or to have declined (where it used to be strong).
Misguided and mismanaged
attempts to reform public administration (see
Decay of Australian Public Administration) and to
commercialize universities may have
contributed to this syndrome;
- businesses generally have been seen to lack the management ability to
conceive or implement the strategic initiatives required to create
competitive advantages or new export markets [1]
A very telling indicator about the under-development of Australia's economy
generally is the difficulty which expatriate Australians, with skills gained
through international experience, reportedly have in gaining employment here -
because their abilities are seen as a threat by their potential bosses [1]
|
Traditional Strategy
|
Queensland's Traditional Economic Strategy
The history of Queensland's economic strategy (eg a touch of socialism in the
1920s; a strong agrarian / state corporatism tradition until 1957) will not be
considered here.
However what is now seen as Queensland's 'traditional' economic strategy (ie that of
the 1980s) involved:
- trying to attract investment (especially that linked to natural resources) by
government support for major investors;
- encouraging population and business growth through relatively low taxes;
and
- provision of minor amounts of government 'assistance' to fill market
gaps.
Queensland's population and economy grew relatively rapidly under this
formula. What was not considered was the poor quality (ie low
value-added) of the industries which it encouraged, eg:
Problems with this formula were that:
- attracting investment, which had been seen as a
key economic development tactic in the industrial era, had lost credibility
in Europe and North America since the 1970s as a path to a high productivity
economy because of competition from low wage economies (see
Comments on Buying Industry).
Developing existing capabilities appeared to be the preferred option;
- the priority given to 'major' projects was
inappropriate, as project size is no guarantee of high economic benefit, and
there is more to be gained by developing economic and administrative systems
as a whole than by central government engagement with isolated 'projects';
- the resource sectors in which growth was being encouraged were seen to
have limited prospects because of low global demand growth and poor terms of
trade. And as noted above, primarily capital intensive production also
appeared to encounter structural obstacles because of low wage competition
from less developed countries
[Note: the latter comments should not be seen as indicating a view that
industries linked to natural resources are inappropriate for Queensland -
merely that naive commercial and economic strategies are inappropriate.
Managing
Australian Mineral Wealth for Sustainable Economic Development (if
combined with competent business and economic strategy) would appear to
point towards very relevant opportunities)
- direct government 'assistance' to firms to fill
market gaps tends
to be the opposite of, and economically inferior to, developing the economy (ie of enhancing the ability of
business and the community to provide the support firms require).
The problem with direct government 'assistance' to
firms is that:
- high quality of advice and assistance about enterprise development or
innovation requires 'market conscious' organizations with relevant experience and
skills. Government agencies have to be more politically than market conscious, and thus tend to provide support of poor technical quality
(or else to be under-resourced);
- public accountability requirements attached to assistance programs will
tend to distort firms' priorities and needs (or, if accountability
constraints are limited, rorts will be likely);
- the budgetary cost of assistance directly reduces the economic
value-added (and contribution to overall economic productivity) of any
resulting activities;
- a well developed economy could provide support for (say) 20 firms for
each one that can be supported from limited public funding, yet the latter
tends to prevent non-governmental support from initially emerging - because it appears
to be free. In other words, while 'assistance' to firms may be provided because
market gaps exist (as they always will in a changing economy) the risk is
that government 'assistance' programs will lock-in those market gaps, and prevent
the economy from developing;
- while creating what appear to be
business
successes under 'hothouse'
conditions can provide political gains for government, those 'successes'
will tend to fail, or be taken over, when serious competition is encountered
because they will not have equally serious support from their business environment;
- it is impossible for authorities to know what type of assistance will
actually improve economic performance;
- government is subjected to political pressures from various interest
groups, and what may have been envisaged as positive support for economic
adjustment risks turning into costly 'business welfare' supported by
entrenched lobby groups.
A better alternative involves stimulating attention to the opportunities
that are available from providing services to fill market gaps - but though
this is not a role which politically accountable organizations can be
relied upon to fulfill adequately,
because political understanding and acceptance of the need will often tend
to be 10-15 years too late.
Furthermore traditionally emphasis was only being given to economic growth ('more'
activity) but not to economic
development ('better' activity).
The difference between 'growth' and 'development' is suggested in
Section 5.1 of SEQ 2001: A Plan
for an Under-developed Economy (1994). In over-simplified terms an emphasis
on 'growth' can yield industries with large receipts and large expenditure -
but where the difference between these (ie the value-added which is counted as
economic 'product' and finances return on investment, wages and salaries and
net payments to government) may be small. An emphasis on 'development' can
increase that difference (by creating competitive advantages for firms) and so
increase community incomes, as well as increasing attractiveness for investment
and growth.
This naive strategy probably arose because:
- natural resource strengths created motives and opportunities for
unsophisticated political and business interests to gain advantages by
announcing (and supporting) 'projects' irrespective of their impact on
community welfare (see
Resource Curse Hypothesis);
- competent institutions in civil society to develop
policy concepts
were virtually non-existent due to the lack of high level strategic
capabilities in Queensland's small business / branch office economy, to a high level of reliance on foreign investment (see
Queensland's
Weak Parliament) and to a tendency by governments to monopolize
information they received (which has been seen as a
general obstacle
to economic development) . Indications of this problem include:
- the 15 year lag which often occurred in introducing advantageous
changes to economic systems and policies, eg
- industrial estates used to receive strong support because this was
believed to be critical the location decisions of manufacturers. In the
absence of serious economic research capabilities it took some 15 years
before anyone realized that industrial estates did not really influence
the location decisions of manufacturers (Berryman J., `Survey of Business
on Queensland's Industrial Estates', Planner, V21, N2 June 1981),
and about another decade before the program was reviewed;
- agribusiness models were standard practice in Europe and north America
by 1980, but not accepted politically in Australia until the early 1990s;
- numerous forums in which the author has participated which were led by
persons with the operational concerns of junior managers and a desire to
lobby government for help, and limited
understanding of policy issues (eg of what government should best do in
the public interest);
- the author's experience in the 1990s of being invited to attend one
discussion with several leading citizens in relation to developing an
economic strategy - where none of those attending seemed to have much real
understanding of how a developed economy works (and thus had little chance
of finding a strategy to create one). The major thrust of their
expectations appeared to revolve around facilitating external investors'
projects;
- the tendency to define value-adding as being equivalent to
downstream processing (eg of agricultural and mineral production) -
though whether economic value is added by such processing is a much more
complex question (see Section
3 of Queensland's Challenge).
- Australia's unbalanced federal financial arrangements spared
Queensland Governments from the financial consequences of their economic
strategies (see
About the Review
of the Grants Commission Arrangements). Key points are that:
- states have most spending responsibilities while the federal
government gains most tax revenues. Horizontal fiscal equalization
arrangements made under the Grants Commission allowed Queensland to
prosper financially despite the weak tax base which its economic
strategies created. Because of this arrangement, Queensland has simply had no
financial incentive to take the development of its economy seriously;
- state taxation largely applied to areas dependent on economic turnover
(eg stamp duty, mineral royalties), rather than to economic value added (eg
income taxes);
- in the 1980s, public finance was defined as the key indicator of
whether Queensland had a 'strong' economy - and this goal dominated over
options that might have yielded greater benefits.
In this environment, there has been little raw material publicly available for debates about
policy issues; and that which is available is of poor quality - eg favouring
operational economic programs (typified by support for foreign investors, or government
programs to 'assist' firms which corresponds to the operational concerns of small business / branch
office managers) rather than developmental actions which enable business and
the community to better assist one another (corresponding to the more
strategic concerns of corporate CEOs).
|
1990's Strategy |
Strategies in the 1990s
An opportunity was available from the late 1980s to adopt a more
sophisticated strategy.
Unfortunately this chance was missed, and four general state economic
strategies from 1987 to 1997 did little but slightly increase (ineffectual)
government 'assistance' to fill market gaps.
The reason that economic strategies in the late 1980s and early 1990s, such as Quality
Queensland and Leading State, did not result in effective
machinery for development of Queensland's economy is suggested in
a 1992 summary
of a review of the Leading State strategy.
The missed opportunity and what went wrong are outlined in
Defects in
Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes and summarized in
Queensland's Challenge (see Section 1).
The latter referred to:
- public recognition of the need for economic change - but not of the fact
that the economic goal posts had been raised by changes in the economies that Queensland /
Australia were seeking to emulate;
- the lack of any substantive change in practice to what was naively seen
as Queensland's 'winning' economic formula;
- the fact that increasing competition (through market
liberalization) is also insufficient to ensure the (often systemic and
institutional)
capabilities required for firms and individuals to compete successfully;
- the role which government 'assistance' to firms has in locking in market
failures and creating bottlenecks that prevent the economy from developing - see also
comments above
A major factor in missing this opportunity was the further weakening of the institutional capacity which Queensland
needs to develop
its economy because 'reform' was undertaken to build a political power base
rather than to improve performance and this damaged the technical
competence of the Public Service (see
Towards
a Professional Public Service for Queensland). Efforts to
develop a productive modern economy, that were frustrated
by the priority given to inappropriate (eg distorted financial) goals in the 1980s, were
often frustrated
in the 1990s by the ignorance and inexperience of those politically
favoured to mis-manage more progressive goals. This is illustrated
by the comments on Smart State below which refer to
methods which might allow its virtuous goals to be achieved that were developed
through experience in the 1980s but then lost through politicisation and de-skilling.
|
21st
Century Populism |
Populism in the Early 21st century
Strategy developed under the present state government has been well meant.
Section 2 of Queensland's Challenge
argued that:
- current strategy in 2001 (like the 1997 strategy of the previous government) had
apparently recognized the vital importance of developing a more productive
economy;
- the emphasis given to innovation was vital if Queensland was to benefit
from, rather than be the victim of, economic change.
But unfortunately the practical competencies required to have any real prospect
of developing a more productive economy in Queensland were not
demonstrated.
In particular government seemed to be trying to force the pace and direction of
economic change.
The Smart State strategy, despite claims
of measurable economic gains, seemed likely to produce mainly short term
applause from a few commentators and benefited interest groups, rather
than resulting in commercially and economically relevant innovation
systems (See A Commentary on Smart State:
Illustrating Queensland's Lack of Realistic Public Policy
and Queensland's Biotechnology
Bubble).
The basis point is that Smart State involves an attempt to force-feed
economic change by (a) funding more 'smart' economic inputs (eg education
and research) and (b) directly stimulating commercial activities based on those
inputs.
The problem with this is that Queensland's mainstream economy is largely
uninvolved because:
- the economy lacks the systemic capabilities required to make highly
productive use of such 'smart' inputs (and this is the main reason that an
innovation-capable economy has not emerged before from the 'smart'
inputs which have always been available); and
- rather than stimulating such systemic capabilities (eg by methods
similar to those suggested in
Developing a
Regional Industry Cluster) government is trying to
directly force commercial gains from its new 'smart' inputs - and, by
doing so, it is reinforcing (rather than eliminating) disabling market gaps and
weaknesses.
If emphasis were given to upgrading the ability of the mainstream economy
to use 'smart' inputs then (a) economic productivity should substantially
increase and (b) returns on funding 'smart' inputs would be significantly
improved.
Further examples of forcing the pace and direction of economic change (and comments on them) include:
- an emphasis on new economic sectors is being seen to be at the expense
of traditional sectors [1]
though, to gain practical results, it is always best to build on what
already works.
- an ambitious program was announced to make IT Queensland's second
biggest industry (Hellaby D., ''Smart state'
gets $1bn', Australian, 7/9/99) [Note 6]
- in discussing the State Government's economic strategy the 2001 budget
documents refer to such issues as creating a competitive business
environment and employment initiatives (2001 Budget Paper
#3,
p3-11) - yet only what government itself is doing in such areas is
considered, and this is only a part (and not the most significant part) of
what 'Queensland' is doing. As noted above, providing government
'assistance' is the opposite of developing the economy (ie of enhancing
the ability of business and the community to provide support)
- efforts are being made (often with large subsidies) to recruit
industry - which is simply not a credible method for building a productive
modern economy (see Buying Industry)
despite its political appeal as a way to show that ‘something is being
done’;
- financial support was provided for a magnesium project (see
Public Investment in Magnesium
Project) which later experienced serious management and financing
problems which
reflected the fact that it was only naive over-confidence which led to the
view that Australian business had the ability to undertake such endeavours;
- numerous other grants and subsidies are provided eg for:
- Targeted Industries (incorporating Queensland Industry Development
Scheme; direct assistance by the Queensland Manufacturing Institute
consultancy services; and support for Industrial Supplies Office) -
efforts that seek to increase exports, investment, innovation and adoption of
e-commerce;
- Regional Business Development - by identification and development of
opportunities;
- Sustainable Technology and Sustainable Energy
- biotechnology (Biostart) [See
Queensland's Biotechnology Bubble]
- research facilities [see About
Queensland's R&D Strategy - which suggests that the real need is
to create a greater business demand for R&D facilities by increasing the economies' ability
to succeed commercially through innovation]
- development of cooperative research centers [see
one observer's assessment of CRC
scheme]
- technology and research parks [see Queensland. Premier's Department,
The Role of Research / Technology parks in Queensland's technological
Development, June 1984 - which suggested that such facilities
provide useful infrastructure in regions with an innovative culture and
ready access to venture capital, but do not in themselves create an
environment ensuring that those pre-conditions emerge];
- seed funding for innovation start-ups;
- collaboration in commercializing R&D and generating intellectual
property
Moreover the Department of State Development seems to: focus excessively on
'large' projects; want to 'develop the state' itself rather than enabling
business and the community to do so; and be intent on involving itself in
'assisting' firms in ways which merely prevent the economy developing.
There have been numerous efforts to 'fix' DSD's problems.
In March 2002 the Department of State Development (DSD)
reportedly outlined a strategy which emphasized: increased exports;
luring head offices north; establishing large projects (including the New
Guinea gas pipeline); DSD as chief advocate for business in the state,
more involved with business and effective as an investment agency; and development of public-private partnerships
[1]. In October 2002
attention was drawn to Queensland's In October 2002 attention was drawn to
Queensland's (a) 19 state
development centers which provide one stop shop support to small enterprises - with
training and help cutting red tape and (b) 24 different grant schemes of which
only one involved incentives to external firms to locate in Queensland [1]
The problem with such arrangements is that:
-
as noted above buying industry
is not a credible way of developing a productive industry cluster;
-
endorsement of investments because they are 'large' (and provide
opportunities for political statements) despite of their low economic productivity, has been a major factor in Queensland’s ongoing economic under-development
(see Section 3 of detailed version of
Queensland's Challenge)
-
DSD's basic mission seems
misguided. It sees its role as developing the ‘state’ (ie involving itself
directly in: assisting business; advocacy on behalf of business; promoting
projects; stimulating exports and investment) rather than in developing the
‘economy’ (ie stimulating the ability of: commerce and industry to provide the
support firms need; and of business and the community to undertake such
strategic operations). The difference is critical to whether Queensland
overcomes:
-
its ‘branch office’ status with an economically dependent
community lacking in strategic business and economic capabilities and
-
its
relatively low community incomes due to encouraging activities which benefit
the ‘state’ (ie the political establishment) rather than those with commercial
payoffs that might benefit the economy;
-
mis-management of the PNG Gas
Pipeline appears likely to give Queensland a poor international reputation in relation
to sovereign risk;
-
public-private
partnerships seem likely to be an unsatisfactory way to achieve their
presumed objectives (ie more efficient delivery of infrastructure and
services, and mobilizing additional financial resources) and offer far less
benefits than private-public partnerships focused on development of industry
clusters;
-
criticism has been leveled at Austrade's efforts in export
development [1]. Are those of the Department of State Development significantly
better?
In April 2003, a strategy for development of manufacturing was announced [1].
While this scheme identified plausible goals (in terms of industry sectors and
economic functions) it contained significant limitations in achieving its
apparent goal of enhancing manufacturers' supply chains. In particular:
- the effect of government 'assistance' can only
be to impart to affected firms a politically-idealized (and thus commercially
sterile) version of the capabilities that are seen as being needed to develop
this sector. The problem in picking winners in terms of industry sectors /
firms is that the information required to do so is too complex and widely
diffused in the economy to be assembled. This same constraint applies to
'picking winners' in terms of best business practices - a judgment for which
there is no general answer
- the goal of the program is stated as 'attracting' venture capital. The
latter involves a combination of (a) money and (b) commercial skills to
support the rapid growth of inexperienced firms. The latter skill would be an
essential part of the supply chain of a well developed local manufacturing
supply chain - not something that should have to be 'attracted'
In April 2004 DSD was 'smartened up' by senior level sackings, reorganization
and assuming responsibility for the Smart State program while the Department of
Innovation and Information Economy (DIIE) was abolished [ 1].
There can be little doubt of the desperate need to 'smarten up' DSD and that
DIIE was not really contributing in a practical way to Queensland's
development (see Commentary on Smart State).
However simply re-organizing a set of poor economic functions can not achieve
anything - any more than rearranging the deck chairs on the Titanic would have
stopped it from sinking.
The intended new arrangement did not reflect a sense of realistic strategic
direction for either DSD or Queensland's economy in the face of
significant economic risks intensifying competitive pressure.
In particular:
- it did not involve strategic R&D machinery (either in-house or preferably
externally) to develop a sense of direction for Queensland's economy as a
whole (or its major industry clusters, or economic regions);
- proposed programs addressed 20 year old agendas (eg facilitating major
projects which had always been suspect, innovation
capabilities the need for which had been identified in the early 1980s and
which could have been in place a decade earlier with a more systematic
approach). Newer types of economic capabilities were not yet properly
reflected in the developmental agenda (eg industry clusters; supply chain
management; global outsourcing);
- emphasis was given to Public Private Partnerships (PPPs) for providing
infrastructure though these are: (a) not in themselves a way of achieving
necessary increase in the amount spent on infrastructure overall - as
government or users still ultimately pay; (b) often an inappropriate way of
seeking value-for-money given that functions become government responsibility
because their complexity causes market failures - and that this complexity
ensures that potential production cost savings via PPPs are likely to be
offset by high contract management costs (see
Public Private Partnerships for
Infrastructure); (c) ideally only a minor issue - as PPPs can only really
be of value for a small percentage of infrastructure projects; and (d) in
practice a serious added complexity in Queensland's already highly
Defective Machinery for Planning and
Delivery of Infrastructure.
- DSD appeared likely to continue undertaking 'business welfare' programs
involving subsidised support to individual firms - whose main
effect is to prevent Queensland's economy from
developing
However some progress may have been in August 2004 when it
appeared that the futility of 'buying industry' with incentives was belatedly
recognized [1]
In July 2005 an attempt was made to rejuvenate DSD by giving it
a higher ministerial status - apparently under the impression that it had
previously been successful when it was a super-department with clout by (a) attracting big name
companies (b) developing new policies (eg for forestry, energy,
water reform and local content purchasing) and (c) handling of redevelopment of Suncorp stadium
- though this did now win it friends, and others subsequently took the
opportunity to get their own back [1].
However the assumption that a politically 'heavy' approach will achieve
economic progress is touchingly naive. For example, many of the claimed
successes achieved by DSD were dubious, eg:
- industrial recruitment ('ie attracting big name companies') is an
amateurish approach to economic
development);
- some policies that were developed were clearly inadequate (eg for energy
[1], water [1],
local content purchasing);
- the redevelopment of Suncorp Stadium was seen by one observer as a prime
example of politics getting in the way of good government [1];
Moreover Queensland's experience in the 1970s and 1980s shows that
systematic organizational development is a
superior way to make government easy to deal with, while central attempts
to force through politically-endorsed (but perhaps relatively unproductive)
projects is counter-productive both economically and by generating conflicts
and breaking down effective governance.
To achieve real progress a
less politically-coercive and
more market-driven approach to Smart State would be a good way to start.
In general trying to force the pace and direction of economic
change will not improve overall economic performance because (a) it is
impossible for authorities in a Western-style democracy to know what actions
should be encouraged because of the complexity and changeability of the
economy and (b) forcing outcomes will stifle the natural mechanisms of the
economy - ie those that are based on initiative by members of the local and
external community.
The predictable outcome is slowing of the overall rate of growth and
change (and also risking fiscal losses). This is
probably a significant factor in Queensland's at-times poor jobs' performance [1, and others). A somewhat
similar phenomenon was associated with the activities of Victoria's Cain
Government in the 1980s (see
The Fall of the House of
Cain) where that government's expensive efforts to force
economic change resulted in worse economic performance than other states
achieved at the same time (and also proved a financial disaster). Even
more significantly:
- Queensland is belatedly struggling to create the type of economic capabilities
(eg Smart State's emphasis on innovation) which were identified in the early
1980s as needed based
on study of best international practices in the 1960s and 1970s. No serious work on more recent
'best practice' requirements (eg supply-chain integration or international
outsourcing based on e-commerce) seems to have been undertaken; and
- while government incentives to achieve social, environmental or
regional goals or to stimulate attention to new economic infrastructure
may be very useful, trying to 'assist' firms by directly filling market gaps is not likely to improve the overall
performance of the economy for reasons outlined
above..
As well as trying to force the pace and direction of economic change:
- Queensland seems currently unable to plan effectively for the provision
of infrastructure (see Defects in
Infrastructure Planning and Delivery in Queensland
).
- government still tends to throttle information flows (see
FOI). In other
words, government is seeking to be Queensland rather than to
govern Queensland.
- observers do not seem to believe that Queensland's industrial relations
system is effective (see article by
McCarthy and
Courier Mail
editorial). An Enterprise Bargaining system that works seems essential -
because flexibility to respond to market changes is critical to raising
economic productivity and business income, and the equitable sharing of
business income is vital to social justice, harmony, strong consumer demand and a
healthy tax base.
- a BCA study concluded that Queensland was the worst state in terms of red
tape affecting business [1].
|
Need
to Do Better |
The Need to Do Better
Despite the long period of strong global economic growth which has been
virtually recession-free, pressure for better economic performance is increasing, because:
- the factors that have allowed global growth to be maintained seem likely
to become unsustainable at some point (see
The Potential
for Economic Instability). The Bank of Japan's decision to end the
process of creating the easy liquidity that has allow countries such as
Australia to fund large current account deficits cheaply seems particularly
significant. [1]
- BIS study suggests that $A is more vulnerable to capital flight than
almost any other currency in the
world because of the growth of Australia's foreign debts. The currencies
at most risk are those most supported by the 'carry trade'.[1]
- the ongoing devaluation that priced Australian's into jobs and gave the
impression of superior economic / productivity growth during the 1990s (see
Impact of Economic
Liberalism in Australia) seems likely to reverse [1] due to changes in
international financial market conditions (especially an easing / reversal of
the strong capital inflow into the US). The increase in $A value to
$US70c cut exporters margins 25% as they can not raise prices [1].
And Australian manufacturers have had a tough time in spite of the strong
growth in the global economy [1,
2].
Treasurer warned of tough conditions facing exporters because of stronger $A
[1]
-
It is getting harder for manufacturers to operate in Australia - because of low cost
overseas competition [1].
- a stronger tax base
is needed due to state financing problems which
have complex causes but are being brought to a head (see
Pressure for Tax Increases). Moreover
increased tax rates can be expected to force some changes in the industrial
structure geared to serving rapid population growth which relatively low tax rates have
encouraged (especially in SE Queensland);
-
Australia's current account deficit has increased to what was seen as 'banana
republic' levels in the 1980s (ie around 6% of GDP) - in spite of the most
favourable terms of trade in a generation. Without that improvement (which is
unlikely to be sustained) the deficit would have been over 15% of GDP [1].
Predictions of increased export values never seem to occur despite record
commodity prices [1]
-
Australia's current account deficit should have significantly improved as
commodity prices have skyrocketed. But in early 2006 export valued have
remained flat, while imports grew rapidly - resulting in near record deficits.
Commodity price boom will end eventually - and see current account in real
difficulties [1];
-
the level of Australia's foreign debt has become a threat to the federal
government's AAA credit rating [1];
- financial deregulation allowed households to gear up (eg by property
investment) which has provided demand to drive strong growth, but created
difficulties in managing a highly leveraged economy because of the effect any
increase in interest rates must have [1];
- growth has been driven by domestic consumption and housing construction (which
involved heavy reliance on credit [1])
but appears
in future to
have to depend on exports [1,
2,
3],
However
-
Australia faces an increasingly difficult trading environment. For example:
- challenges are merging to economic globalization because job
creation and increasing real wages have slowed in the mature, industrialized economies
as the Internet has changed the way business is done. Previously rich countries would lose
market share in manufacturing but this was not a
serious threat because they had many highly-educated knowledge workers in services.
This distinction is now disappearing. Gains in the developing world are
increasingly at the expense of the developed world. [1]
-
in order to increase productivity in this environment it, another 'new'
business model appears to have emerged - involving 'platform companies' geared
to exploiting the current global organization of production. [1]
Such models do not yet appear to have received attention in Queensland;
- US demand has driven global growth for more than a decade - but seems
unlikely to be able to continue doing so given the US's resulting financial
imbalances, Moreover it is not clear that alternative growth drivers are
available (see
Structural Incompatibility Puts Global Growth at Risk);
- international trade has declined in the less certain environment that
has emerged since 2001, and Australia's share of export markets has fallen [1];
- given the September 2003 breakdown of global trade talks, a free trade agreement
with the US has been seen as best remaining prospect for major new export
markets [1,
2];
- export growth has stagnated [1,
2]. In particular Australia's exports have fallen
for 3 years; domestic costs
have risen faster than trading partners; the development of a FTA with US has
not prevented the latter from increasing protectionism; Canada's experience with a US FTA with US was of declining exports to other markets; discrimination in
third markets is rising because of other US FTAs [1].
Manufacturing, which was a major driver of export growth in the early 1990s,
has suffered setbacks as a result of: Chinese competition; less favourable
exchange rates; and increasing outward manufacturing investment [1]. On the other hand, others have seen evidence of good export performance over a longer
time scale [1,
2], and
the Reserve Bank ascribed Australia's export slowdown to a lack of resource
investments between 1998 and 2000 [1]
- infrastructure bottlenecks are seen as one factor constraining exports [1,
2,
3], as has a
lack of relevant skills [1,
2,
3]. Queensland in particular
has been seen to have good growth prospects which are at risk from
infrastructure bottlenecks [1]. Problems
in attempting to regulate privately owned 'public' goods (eg those with a
monopoly character) may be a factor in one case [1];
-
businesses are generally seen to lack the management ability to identify and
implement the sorts of strategic initiatives required for development of
exports [1];
-
attempts to support / encourage innovation have been suggested to be based on
poor understanding of how this is undertaken in Australia [1,
2];
-
Australia has enjoyed rapid increases in income but has not spent / invested
the money wisely in new productive capabilities [1]
-
a large percentage of individual workers have been shown to be suffering
unhealthy and unsustainable levels of work stress [1];
-
significant shortages of skilled workers are a constraint on growth [1,
2];
-
while there has been a high rate of job creation, this has often been of poor
quality. Large numbers of jobs are shifting from full to part time status [1]
-
Australia (Queensland in particular) will need to
rely on elderly, disabled and parents of school age children because of worker
shortage due to rapidly aging population over the next five years [1]
-
future growth is likely to be more difficult because past growth has been
driven by improved terms of trade (which are likely to start to decline) [1]
-
the rapid growth which is occurring in Asia will change the character of of
global markets [1], and Australia has traditionally been uncomfortable doing
business (other than selling commodities) in that region because of
significantly different cultural features [1];
-
Australia's manufacturing and services exports have been declining - being
offset by increased commodities exports to China on whose continuance
Australia's export future now seems likely to depend [1].
In particular another resource boom is now expected [1]
-
major new opportunities (eg for commodities, services) are seen to be
emerging from economic reform and rapid development in China [1]
- however China's progress seems unlikely to be sustainable (see
China's
Development: Assessing the Implications). Around April 2004 an intention
to slow China's growth (which could potentially reflect structural rather
than cyclical factors) was announced (see
Slowdown or Crisis?). In October 2005, the state government suggested
that for the first time event strong growth for 30-40 years could be expected
based on coal exports [1],
while some other observers highlighted the volatility of resource markets and
thus the downside risk [1]. In
January 2006 the World Bank argued that China's growth pattern is
unsustainable - because it is based on cheap capital. Rapid gains in
manufacturing productivity and stagnant agricultural productivity drive
inequality. Growth can't be sustained without household demand and service
industries a reduced emphasis on manufacturing exports (and resource inputs)
and greater emphasis on agricultural exports. [1]
-
though commodity prices are very high - but so are production and construction costs, as
the
mining sector struggles to expand [1];
-
major industries face environmental risks (eg related to
greenhouse gas reduction
[1];
salinity;
access to water;
Great Artesian
Basin; Great Barrier
Reef). It is also possible el
Nino or other climatic influences could change weather patterns permanently
from the historically benign patterns of recent centuries;
-
agriculture, traditionally an important industry, faces significant
environmental challenges related to water as well as poor and deteriorating
soil quality [1]
- problems which have led to substantial adjustments in recent years [1],
and to suggestions that the scale of the industry needs to be significantly
phased back [1]
- prior to the emergence of a new resource boom associated with China's
growth surge, currently important mineral and energy industries also faced significant
challenges which must be met if those industries are to have more than a boom
/ bust character.
In particular:
- there was a probable need to re-invent capital-intensive strategies for resource-based
industries (which were major drivers of investment in the 1990s) because of
changes in their competitive environment.
Detail: Queensland / Australia's resources firms generally had low return on capital
in the 1990s. Amongst the reasons for this is the lack of market power
that is available to producers of undifferentiated commodities (ie prices
tend to get bid down to just above production costs) and the strong
competition from low-wage developing countries. However value added is
possible from later-stage processing - which is a demand, rather than
supply, driven
and thus provides producers with market power. To restore decent
profit margins leading resource
firms are now looking at strategies such as value-chain management (ie involvement at all
stages from mine to market) and aggregation of supply (to gain more
market power). However
Queensland's unsophisticated
Department of State Development seems to be pursuing an antiquated approach
to adding value - involving downstream processing only
to the stage of undifferentiated commodities which simply makes no
commercial sense.
- the lack of an effective industry cluster (ie of supportive commercial
and technological functions) led to project failures and loss of
control [1,
2]
- subsidized Chinese coal was threatening Australia's dominance of global
coal markets [1];
- Queensland regulatory regime for minerals and energy has been seen as
hopeless [1];
- anecdotal evidence suggests that China (which has immense resource
endowments and low wages) appears likely to skip the 'basic processing'
emphasis and move directly into competing on the basis of the strategies of
the leading firms (eg value-chain management). This is a feasible option
because it suits the effective bureaucratically-endorsed networking / consultation within 'Chinese' communities.
Combining low
wage competition with leading-edge methods also parallels the strategy Japan used to catch up with / surpass Western
countries in manufacturing. Moreover:
- the attractiveness of mineral rich locations in Australia may diminish,
because surface geology suggests that the mineral potential of East and South
Asian (especially China) is immense, and sufficient for their future needs.
Infrastructure, environmental and social challenges need to be overcome but
the resources will probably be proven upwards while hydro power potential
(and other alternative energy potentials) will also have a significant
impact.
-
native title and environmental currently constrain access to resources, and
there is a future need to develop protocols for linking mining with alternative surface uses (native title; recreation; water; farming; ecology);
- global efforts (via
OECD Chemical Risk Reduction Program) to reduce
health risks are proscribing materials that are
targeted for elimination (eg copper, lead, zinc, polyethylene triglycerides which are
significant in Queensland's economy);
- the introduction of full environmental and social costing on corporate balance sheets as good business
practice will reshape perceived costs and focus attention on areas that
are socially and environmentally acceptable to mine - which could be
significant for Australia given native title and ecosystem sensitivities;
- the cost of greenhouse emissions is becoming a significant factor in
evaluating major investments [1]
- improvements in geophysical techniques that allow geological resource
endowments at depth to be defined will become standard;
- the environmental implication of mining need attention especially:
- relationship with ecosystems containing biological resources of currently
unknown value;
- effect of water constraints (eg World Heritage listed Great Barrier Reef - which has important biological diversity;
Gulf of Carpentaria which is
shallow and sensitive; Great Artesian Basin where the effect of mining and land clearing is
unknown).
- a serious skills deficiency has affected the industry because of the
closing of many university departments world-wide that had provided graduates
[1]
-
Australia has been said to be experiencing the effect of a
'resource curse' in 2006. Because things are too easy,
there is no imperative for political or economic
reform, as it is believed that
good times will last forever .[1]
- the sustainability of growth based on a resource boom is uncertain. In the
past such booms have proven highly unstable and have been suggested to adversely
affect other industries (eg by altering their competitiveness through affecting
the exchange rate). It has been suggested that speculators seeking a hedge
against a structural decline in the status of the $US could be a factor in the
resource boom in 2005 [1]
-
Australia has lost its attraction for exploration, as miners seek to get the most out of existing sites
rather than develop new ones, arguably because subsidies in the form of tax
advantages are required to attract explorers. [1]
- many regions are experiencing economic difficulties (see
above);
- some social difficulties appear to have economic implications - in
particular:
- market liberalization, which has allowed economic adjustment in Australia,
has been accompanied by increased inequality - as much job creation has been of
poor quality with low incomes. Those trapped in low incomes or long term
unemployment are seen to be emerging as an underclass (see
above). Reasonable equity has been maintained to
date by increases in welfare payments (which erode the benefits of
higher productivity and translate into increasing dependency).
Overcoming such problems ultimately requires (amongst other things) an economic regime able to create
accessible higher-income job opportunities;
- an 'asset economy' (ie one in which demand is financed more by increasing
asset values, rather than by income) has been suggested to exist in the US [1]
- and seems likely to have emerged in Australia also. The incomes of the
'middle-class' have tended to stagnate [1] (presumably because of the effect of outsourcing
of increasingly high-skill jobs to low wage economies) and consumption has
increasingly been
maintained on the basis of escalating asset values. When / if this bubble
bursts, the problem of income inequality (with its adverse implications for
political stability) could be well beyond being corrected by government welfare
payments unless something has been done to upgrade the ability of the economy to
generate large numbers of high-paid jobs;
- the ethical foundations on which Australia's legal and governance systems
have assumed individual liberty (an arrangement which has very significant
economic benefits) appear to have been eroding (see
Moral Foundations
of Individual Liberty);
- there is a need to strengthen all aspects of developed societies to overcome threats
apparently posed by extremists favouring pre-modern social, political and
economic systems (eg see
Discouraging Pointless Extremism).
And a related significant concern arises from the potential security risks
associated with ineffective economic and political systems in many neighbouring
nations.
- the Free Trade Agreement with the US must expose firms directly to the
most competitive business environment in the world, and one in which the
research and lobbying by organized groups is also more intense and competitive
than elsewhere.
Moreover there are indications of significant changes in the global economic
environment that will create competitive pressures requiring a new round of
structural changes in all relatively developed economies.
In particular:
- since the 1960s the competitive challenge from low cost Asian
manufacturing (initially Japan, then the 'tigers' and China) has (a)
required developed regions to relocate industry,
adopt knowledge based
competitive strategies and change industry
structure especially towards high-value services and (b) contained
inflation by depriving manufacturers of pricing power. This trend seems
likely to intensify for some time as a result of China's further development
[1;
2, 3] though there may
well be long term limitations (see
China's
Development: Assessing the Implications). The Treasurer suggested that
low cost manufacturing has no future in Australia given a free trade
agreement with China [1];
- India may be pursuing a similar strategy with respect to the services
industries into which developed economies have diversified [1]. In
this respect India's English language background would provide a competitive
advantage not widely available to developing nations. India is also
developing very rapidly in research intensive manufacturing [1],
and is competing with low wages for highly qualified people in areas which go
well beyond call centers [1,
2];
- there is a massive world-wide shift to outsourcing based on the use of
the Internet - especially to China and India - whose implications have not
been taken into account by Australian firms who have relied on a property
bubble and cost cutting [1]
- developing Asia will be likely to shift into more knowledge intensive
(rather than low cost) industries - and place further competitive pressure on
areas into which more developed economies have been diversifying. Indications
of this include:
- China's growth is not simply (as many have assumed) a major export market
- but rather a source of competition (both from China and elsewhere) that
will challenge many Australian industries [1];
- a medium to long term shift away from low-cost production strategies will
remove the protection against inflation which developed economies have
enjoyed in the 1990s - which had allowed loose monetary policies and very
rapid growth.
Something new now clearly needs to be tried because these trends have
apparently made it virtually impossible for developed economies to increase
real income levels (as the Internet allows globalization of the service
industries which had previously provided scope to continue increasing incomes
as manufacturing migrated to lower wage economies [1].
|
Solutions? |
What could be done?
Behind the growth which has been sustained by potentially unstable global
economic bubbles, many specific areas of structural weakness in Queensland's current economic
situation have been mentioned above including:
- low economic productivity, under-employment and high unemployment;
- weak tax base and exposed public finance;
- lack of machinery for effective planning and delivery of infrastructure,
and potential for losses by infrastructure GOCs in a competitive environment;
- exposure of major industries to environmental constraints and tough
competition;
- struggling regions;
- unrealistic 'populist' economic programs; and
- inflexibility due to lack of effective mechanisms for enterprise
bargaining.
However the root cause of these difficulties is probably that Queensland
lacks adequate machinery to deal with economic change.
The effectiveness of an economy in generating wealth and jobs depends heavily on
the support which exists for business activity (from customers, regulators,
suppliers etc). The business environment involves far more than what can be
seen as 'good' government policy and programs.
Over the past two decades mainstream economics has
concluded (on fairly reasonable grounds) that prospects for economic growth and
development are optimized when government creates a stable and supportive
environment for private enterprise by constantly seeking to provide:
- a rule of law, a reliable basis for contracts, and a simple
legislative / regulatory regime;
- systems of weights, measures and prices;
- a competitive market environment;
- stable monetary policy - characterized by no significant inflation /
deflation;
- fiscal policy which balances budgets over business cycle, and involves
reasonable taxation;
- measures to promote social equity (and a 'safety net'), stimulate less
developed regions, counter business cycles, ensure environmental
responsibility, encourage adjustment in failing industries;
- efficient public goods and services (ie those subject to market
failures);
- investments in human capital (education, training, health) and in
pre-competitive information assets (eg basic research);
- agreement with other governments which permit trade, investment,
people movement;
- sufficient understanding of the business environment to avoid doing
accidental damage in seeking to achieve other goals.
However government only provides a minor part of the environment for
private enterprise. The greater part of their environment is accounted for by:
- the community (as workers, customers, holders of knowledge / skills,
savers / investors, voters);
- other businesses as competitors, suppliers, service providers,
financiers, customers, parallel customers of the same suppliers / service
providers, or simply other occupants of the same economic space; and
- other organizations concerned with economic / social functions (eg
education and training, public information, health) directed to community
or business.
Furthermore the rate of change in individual businesses and in their
supportive environment in response to changing market demands and technologies
can be critical to the ability of business to be economically productive and
thus to produce high returns to investors, employees and governments. This is
because in a competitive environment the productivity of any given activity
will always tend to be reduced over time, requiring a shift into new activities
to escape (for a time) from the competitive pressure.
Economic development can be thought of as a learning process affecting the
overall economic environment (ie involving identification of
opportunities and threats and re-organizing to respond). Economic growth
theory recognizes that knowledge has the key role in generating growth. However
economists have not properly understood that this arises mainly because knowledge
allows (and encourages) economic systems to change rather than by providing an
input to an economic system (see
Defects in
Economic Tactics, Strategy and Outcomes). Innovation within
individual enterprises is only one of various levels at which this effect
can arise.
One practical
implication of taking a broader view of the scope for economic 'learning' is the potential for
creating effective leading-edge mechanisms to
accelerate the development of industry
clusters as a whole. In Queensland's case this might be directed initially to (say) agribusiness; minerals and energy;
and globally focused SMEs, and this (given a basic governance framework along the
lines outlined above) could significantly transform Queensland's economic potential over 5-10
years whilst also building in the ingredients required by social and
environmental challenges.
The main obstacle to accelerating the development of economic subsystems to
provide stronger support to individual enterprises is that Queensland generally lacks
civil institutions
(eg associations, research institutes, foundations, financial institutions,
regional development bodies) which competently undertake serious and applied R&D in relation to
Queensland's economic and industrial functions. In the absence of such entities:
- Queensland: has a relatively low productivity economy and a
weak tax base; and remains a branch office state, because:
- diversification away from traditional economic functions with low
added-value is slow;
- no one is able to take effective leadership roles in development of
industry clusters (which are the environment that individual enterprises
depend upon for support) because politically accountable entities
can not do this in a market-relevant way due to the pressures and
expectations they are subjected to (see
Economic solutions appear
to be beyond politics);
- business, media and the public lack access to strategic economic
intelligence (which is the basis for building the competitive advantages
required for higher productivity);
- interstate migration (encouraged by cheaper taxation and housing) has the
effect of reducing the productive capabilities of the state's human capital [1].
- systematic 'analysis' of Queensland's financial and economic position
tends to be misleading because it ignores
structural defects [1;
2; 3]
- For example, the latter referred to an analysis which continued a
tradition long popular with Queensland's Treasury of placing a
'spin' on the state's economy that prevents attention to its structural problems. Its
economy was
labeled 'strong' and a 'buy' despite having very low per capita incomes by Australia's
declining standards
(which also translates into a weak tax base, and the need for fiscal subsidy through
Grant's Commissions horizontal
equalization). Why would continued growth by tourism (a generally
low productivity sector)
and mining (which had very poor returns for structural reasons
in the 1990s) automatically be good? Why would an investment surge triggered
by population growth and government subsidies (see
Buying Industry) be a sign of
economic prowess? Describing an unprofitable business as 'strong'
and a
'buy' - just because it is growing - is the sort of analysis that contributed to
the dot-com bubble in the US, and to the
Asian financial crisis;
- More realistic analysis would expose the limited competencies of the
leaders of politically influential interest groups - and tends to be strongly
resisted;
- Queensland's political process is poor and populist (and Parliament and
Oppositions have traditionally been weak relative to incumbent governments) -
as outlined above;
- many people just give up on Queensland (despite its lifestyle
advantages) because of the traditional ignorance and autocratic
destructiveness of the political system (see
Authoritarian Government in Queensland?).
Also of concern is the lack of professional credibility and competence in
Queensland's Public Service that has been politically induced for more than a
decade - which further inhibits the effectiveness of the political system and government administration.
An appropriate strategic response by Queensland leaders might involve:
- strengthening of civil institutions required to (a) provide business and
the community with more relevant intelligence (b) stimulate leading-edge market-relevant changes
to economic systems as a whole by the development of cross-functional indicative plans and (c) overcome the chronic
weakness of the political system by providing informed raw material
for public policy debates;
- an emphasis on the development of competitive advantages (rather than
reliance given comparative advantages) to
advance the
prospects of regional economies. In practice this would result in development of regional industry clusters (say those linked to agribusiness,
minerals and energy and globally-focused SMEs) using methods like those
in
Developing a Regional Industry Cluster. Effective use of such methods
outside SE Queensland in particular might create viable alternative
population 'magnets' which would reduce problems associated with growth
management in SE Queensland (see Growth
Management in SE Queensland).
- government programs based on similar methods to stimulate market
mechanisms (eg information, institutions) to accelerate economic change in
'trailing-edge' regions and sectors (ie those being left behind).
While government can not be relied upon to pick economic winners, it can
be expected to identify economic losers - and needs means to respond to them without merely imposing regulations or subsidies
which impede change and development;
- developing government's role as a demanding customer eg by (a) seeking
leading edge technologies in undertaking public functions - where appropriate
and (b) using service delivery and procurement processes which support the
development of those capabilities in firms;
- reducing Queensland's low-cost attractions as a destination for
interstate migration because of the adverse effect which this has on the
quality of the state's human capital [1].
Higher tax rates would allow numerous
apparent spending obligations to finally be funded. Reduced migration would also require changes in the structure of industries that depend on
rapid population growth, and reduce both public revenues and expenditure demands.
- increased concern for international economic and political conditions
involving perhaps (a) efforts to cooperate with neighbouring nations in the
development of civil institutions as outlined in
South Land
Connections project and (b) creation of an international order better
able to provide for general social, environmental and economic welfare - eg
as suggested in
New Manhattan
Project
- re-creating an effective system of professional accountability for the
Public Service so that it is able to provide competent support with public
policy formulation / implementation and in delivery of services /
infrastructure (see Renewal of Queensland's Public
Service and Accountability of
Queensland's Senior Public Servants).
Political leaders could contribute to stronger civil institutions in
Queensland by:
- publicly asking strategically important questions (eg is Smart State a
realistic process for developing economic capabilities?), and emphasis on
identifying and endorsing the economic validity of others' R&D rather
than trying to undertake basic economic research, because:
- it is easier to build credibility by pointing out important questions,
than by guessing the answers to such questions when one does not have
enough information to do so competently;
- general understanding / support / action is needed from the community
and business for any political agenda to work;
- stimulating many (say 20-30) credible independent (non-government non-political)
entities in various functions, sectors and regions to start serious
economic and industrial R&D. Stimulation might involve (a) asking important
questions - as above (b) dissemination of information about public economic policies and programs
and (c) highlighting to business and the community the non-governmental resourcing needs that
such entities have if they are to raise Queensland's economic and
industrial capabilities in the longer term. The desired output of such
entities (of which some 5-10 might be might prove effective and successful in
the long term) might be:
- formulation of 'enterprising' options for enhancing economic (or
community) systems in the form of indicative plans that might be
implemented by the collaborative effort of several existing organizations
and require no special government
support, and enabling those who may have an enterprising interest in such
options to study and evaluate them; and in parallel
- identification of public policy issues that emerge to a relevant
Committee established by Parliament to report to it periodically on such evidence, and also to the public through the
media or publications. These proposals would become one basis of stronger
public policy debate.
- identification of 'models' through which such civil institutions might be
expected to act in the public interest while producing both these types of
outputs, and accepting advice preferentially from those who conform to such a
model;
-
give the State Government a financial incentive to
develop a productive modern economy by phasing out the interstate financial transfers to
Queensland under
Commonwealth Grant's Commission horizontal equalization arrangements. At
present those transfers mean that Queensland's weak tax base can be ignored.
However if there were no such transfers the retention of the financial benefits
that flow from strengthening the tax base would motivate all state
governments to get very serious about economic strategy. Naturally such an
approach could only be viable if methods whereby progress
might genuinely be made were widely supported (as incentive without capability
can translate into failure).
Revised October 2002
|
Queensland Economists Need
to Look at China's Financial Predicament |
Queensland Economists Need to Look at China's Financial Predicament - email sent 12/2/17
Gene Tunny,
Queensland Economy Watch
RE: HSBC’s
Paul Bloxham on the economic outlook and President Trump, Queensland
Economy Watch, 11/2/17
HSBC’s recently-expressed enthusiasm about Australia’s
/ Queensland’s economic prospects that you reported seemed somewhat
unrealistic. Australia’s close ties with China / Asia and a rebound in
commodity prices were the main basis for that enthusiasm (along with potential
agricultural export opportunities in the event of a China / US trade war).
However there seems to have been a general consensus
amongst those who have studied China’s financial situation that it is likely
to experience a financial / debt crisis (see
China’s
Economic Sustainability) and that China’s regime accepted in late 2016
that ‘business as usual’ was too dangerous to continue (see
Recognising
the Problem). While well-considered analyses of the implications
of this have not yet been published, the immediate effect seems to have been a
virtual shutdown in outward investment from China.
Outline
of Montgomery R.,
Don’t
expect Chinese to keep underpinning property market, 11/2/17, The
Australian, 11/7/16: Investors need to
seriously consider China - as government has established
controls that will have a dramatic effect on capital outflow. This needs to
be recognized by: (a) property investors; and (b) equity investors into China.
China's forex reserves are used to stem depreciation of yuan - and have been
falling quickly. While $1tr of foreign exchange had flowed out of China
over previous 18 month, this fell to nil in December 2016. Major developers are
likely to see increased settlement risk. China's government will eventually
need to devalue yuan. China's credit system is coming to a halt. Credit excesses
in China have built up more than in other countries prior to crises. Recent
growth has been driven by unsustainable state-led infrastructure spending - thus
driving up iron ore prices. Credit in China's banking system rose from $3tr in
2006 to $34tr in 2015 - and many of these loans will turn bad. Rising bond
defaults and cancellation of bond issues are signs of rising pressure on banks.
PBOC has injected liquidity and cut reserve requirements for banks. A
recapitalization is inevitable. The real test will be the large number of junk
bond maturities in 2017 and 2018. Over the past 18 months debt rose $6.5tr while
deposits grew $3tr
My attempt to identify the financial implications and
structural causes of China’s debt crisis are in
China's
Likely 2017 Financial Crisis and
Why
China Has a Financial Problem respectively. The former suggests that merely
blocking outward foreign investment is unlikely to be sufficient to stabilize
China’s dangerously high debt / GDP ratio (ie a ‘hard landing’
may be unavoidable), while the latter suggests that there seems to be a
structural incompatibility between China’s current
non-Communist system of
socio-political-economy and its continued economic advancement.
While HSBC may be unaware of China’s difficulties, it
would seem desirable for (say) the Economic Society of Australia (Qld) to
arrange a presentation at which they are explored. They are, after all,
critical to the level of future demand for mineral, energy and agricultural
commodities that Queensland should anticipate from China (and a China-led Asia
more generally).
John Craig
|