Introduction +
Addenda
|
Introduction
Increasingly problems are perceived in Australia's system of government that
require changes to the federal system. Solutions are often suggested through
increasing control by the federal government over originally-state functions,
or the elimination of state governments entirely.
Examples
of the Case for Greater CentralizationGiven national school curriculum and proposed
federal takeover of hospital funding, it may be timely to consider
abolishing state governments. Critics suggest that reform is overdue, and
that states are increasingly irrelevant. Education and Health are the
largest state departments, and if frontline staff answer to Canberra - why
not transfer all responsibility there? A poll found that 56% of people
thought that states should be scrapped to reduce cost of bureaucracy. States
suggest that people have most contact with them - but this is being eroded.
Mark Drummond (convenor of
Beyond Federation) argues that duplications in federal and state systems
cost $20bn pa. Drummond (a Canberra based teacher) argues that a national
curriculum is a welcome move, and there are many areas where states have
adopted a common approach. Since federation states have been defending their
existence and jostling with federal authorities over powers since 1976. John
Pyke (a constitutional lawyer at QUT) found that different schooling systems
caused problems and welcomes a national curriculum. Critics of abolishing
states argue that handing control to Canberra will result in remote areas
missing out. Pyke argues that telecommunications makes this concern
irrelevant, while Drummond believes that similar front-line services would
be provided - all that would be missing was costs of state administrations.
(Lund M. 'Time
to put the nation on the same service track', Courier Mai,
5/3/10)
States have
backed a greater role for the federal government in planning Australia's
cities - because there is a need for federal funds to unlock traffic gridlock
(Hepworth A etal 'States back federal city plans', AFR, 6-7/3/10)
Do states still matter? No PM will concede states have fewer rights but all
since Billy Hughes have happily accepted more power. The states will be even
more impotent when federal government changes GST funding. New initiatives to
increase centralisation include: bypassing states in funding hospitals and
national education curriculum. 64% of Queenslanders want to see end of state
boundaries. Federalism leads to huge bureaucratic duplication and overlap.
Some will warn that service delivery by Canberra will lead to failures - but
states do so also. The rational for federalism in 1800s was (a) defending
liberty through dividing power (b) governing in accord with regional needs and
(c) responding to poor transport and communication. Now it is inappropriate
because of well developed national democratic tradition; good communications /
transport; and little geographically-based cultural differences. However the
problems of constitutional change would be huge. Also (a) there is a need to
bypass political short-termism (b) there would be a need for additional
regional representation - eg in the senate and (c) a long lead time would be
essential. (Williams P., 'Shift the state of play', Courier Mail,
9/3/10)
Since efforts were first made to convince Queenslanders of the need for higher
urban densities, efforts to manage population growth have been mixed. The
Urban Renewal Taskforce transformer some suburbs, but Brisbane's urban area
expanded by 65% and commuter travel averages increased from 13.7 to 15.3 km.
Greenfield development has continued to dominate. The state government paid
lip service to the problem, while the federal government ignored it. The
Queensland Government adopted a SEQ Regional Plan intended to reduce sprawl
and get more benefits from public transport, but did nothing. Only recently
has it sought to gain control of the population debate. While polling suggests
some public support for the medium density housing the state is promoting,
this is easy to counteract. The government's great hope is the Urban Land
Development Authority - and its vision for Fitzgibbon as a high density
suburb. But its efforts have lost focus because so many interests are
involved. The federal government (via Maxine McKew) indicates a desire to
manage the region's rapid growth as a 'partner' with state and local
governments. Also the PM has visions of a 'big Australia' which raises further
concerns about managing population growth'. Commonwealth involvement (to get
more sophisticated policy making, and break down barriers, is to be welcomed
(Johnstone C., 'Growing pains need a shot of federal medicine', Courier
mail, 20-12/3/10)
PM originally proposed a referendum on whether commonwealth should take over
health functions - but there is increasing reason to extend this to consider
whether states should be eliminated entirely (Keane B. 'Do
we still need state governments?', Crikey, 19/4/10)
Federal government was right to try to take important issues like health from
states. State Treasurers fear further federal raids on their GST revenues -
but people have learned that nationally important issues can't be left to
states. These areas now include: hospitals, mental health and state schools.
In the future it will include the urban environment and failures in planning
for transport. The federal governments main means of influence is money and
states, while failing to meet service delivery responsibilities, have allowed
themselves to become dependent on commonwealth revenue (a collective failure
of states). They complain about VFI - but they have have economically
efficient tax bases which they choose not to use properly (eg payroll taxes).
The latter can be economically efficient - and was transferred to states in
1971 to provide a growth tax (as GST was), but states have squandered it with
vote-buying exemptions. States have shown no more interest in providing
quality services than in raising the money to pay for them. Federalists claim
that this is the fault of Canberra's centralist tendencies - and that if
states were given more responsibilities they would improve. This may be true
but why bother? The federal government is right to do to states what the
latter have done to local government - push them into role of subordinates.
PM's health reform provides a roght model - under which federal government
will purchase state services. The states will be suppliers but not necessarily
the only suppliers in the long term. Federal state partnership in health will
be like that between Woolworths and its suppliers - ie one side is much
stronger. And the people like the sound of this (Mitchell A.,
'People have lost faith in the states', AFR,
States are losing a long term battle to retain their power / income.
Australia's federation is decaying. John Howard despised it. Kevin Rudd spoke
of cooperative federalism, but has proven to be like Howard (as shown by
original health reform package) The Opposition leader, takes a similar view to
Rudd. (Craven G 'For states, its all an ACT' AFR, 10/5/10)
This preliminary document will suggest that, while there are serious problems
in Australia's federal system, what has typically been popularly seen as the
obvious 'fix'
(ie increased central control) has been one major cause of current problems,
and that there is probably a simpler and better
alternative.
Moreover the more further centralization is sought as a 'quick fix' to
particular problems that are due to defects in the federal system, the worse
Australia's whole system of government will become.
An addendum includes comments on one observer's
recognition of the need to
move beyond the widespread view in the community that 'more centralization' is
the best cure for anything that ails government.
Other observers have also taken up the question of how Australia's federal system might
be rejuvenated.
Cooperative federalism looks like old premier's conferences - under which
premiers express outrage at miserly funding. Howard's decision to shift GST to
states was supposed to end this - and it did for a while. Now federal
government has taken 1/3 of this back. Now voters tend to favour abolishing
states - but they are entrenched in constitution and are a counter-weight to
Canberra. State power is likely to continue withering. Voters don't think they
do a good job in service delivery. Some (eg Queensland Treasurer Andrew
Fraser) argues that this results from their inability to control own destiny.
State sovereignty without fiscal sovereignty is seen as unrealistic. PM's
approach to health has been to try to increase commonwealth control to match
its fiscal clout. But there are constitutional limits to this. OECD says that
Australia's fiscal imbalance is greater than any federation except Belgium.
The states have expressed concerns about these imbalances. Fraser proposed
state income taxing 2 years ago - and Australia is the only federation in
which states don't levy income taxes. They have constitutional power to do
this - but find it politically easier to beg to Canberra. Given that Australia
is stuck with states, there is a need to make them work properly (Steketee M.,
' Federalism
is a dead idea. So what now?', Australian, 24-25/4/10) At end of
2010 election campaign PM implored voters to distinguish between state
governments and her government - as she wanted her positive economic plan
not to be ignored because of concern for poorly performing state
governments. But at the same time she (and the Opposition) mainly focused
election promises on what the community would expect from state governments.
A Victorian premier once accurately predicted that the time would come when
the federal government would be blamed for everything. Recent developments
reflect final stage of long trend towards trashing the principles that
underpin Australia's federation. Rudd Government undermined federalism in
the name of ending blame game and seamless national economy. Ending blame
game involved maximum possible centralisation of functions - or setting
complex bureaucratic rules to force states to comply with targets set by
Canberra in exchange for funds (as was the case for health and hospital
reform package - which is now increasingly being criticised). Similarly
business concerns about reducing the burden of differences in state
regulations resulted in the creation of unworkable mechanisms through COAG.
The latter has had some successes (eg with occupational health and safety
laws) but most of its working parties are now largely defunct. WA premier
argues that they merely resulted in duplication and confusion. Even more
serious is that costs of regulatory differences were grossly overstated - as
competitive federalism always acted to favour improved regulation and
minimize differences. Similarly mining taxes reflect further confusion about
federalism. Arguing that all Australians deserve to benefit from mineral
wealth overlooks the fact that under Grants Commission adjustments are made
to federal grants where states gain substantial mineral revenues. Present
system actually penalises states for efforts they might make to improve tax
regimes. When first established federal government was expected to have
functions that apply to the whole country, and that the states would remain
autonomous. However the federation is now in trouble because of ambitious /
misguided federal politicians, gross vertical fiscal imbalances and a
centralising high Court. Experience shows that federal systems produce
better economic outcomes than unitary states. Thus there is a need to reform
Australia's federal system so as to reinvigorate state governments. (Sloan
J.
'Stronger states the key to wealth', The Australian, 31/8/10)
Better outcomes are possible when states
are not subject to federal government dictates. Most federal politicians are
centralists, who see states as an annoyance. They talk of cooperative
federalism but this merely refers to federal bureaucracy dominating state
bureaucracy. Many believe federalism just means duplication – but well
functioning federations everywhere (eh Switzerland, US, Canada, Germany)
involve competition, not cooperation. In US both states and federal
government have income tax powers – and people have a choice between living
in high taxing / high service states, or the reverse. Diversity in school
curriculum leads to improvement over time. In Australia the proposed ‘one
size fits all’ curriculum is not impressive. And effective federations tend
to be wealthier than unitary states. It is wrong to assume that cental
government will spend money more efficiently than states, and that outcomes
should be the same everywhere. . Australia’s federal system is in disarray –
because of High Court’s bad decisions to always side with Commonwealth over
the states. Australia has the worst possible vertical fiscal imbalance,
because (unlike functioning federal democracies) the states don’t have
income tax powers. Conferences on fixing the federal system are not what is
needed – rather getting tax powers back to the states is. In Canada premiers
often tell national prime minister to get stuffed. But those in Australia
are too weak – because standing up to centralising bullies would see one’s
share of tax revenues cut. Working in a university shows every day the
defects in one-size-fits-all regulation. Capitalism looks chaotic and has
loads of duplication / failures compared with a centrally controlled
economy. But the former outperforms the latter. Those who favour centralism:
(a) think those at the centre have sufficient information and skill to make
better decisions than through a decentralised arrangement; and (b) dislike
having different regimes and competition (Allan J. 'Colin
Barnett is doing us all a favour by standing up to Canberra, The
Australian, 30/5/11).
A senior commonwealth public servant has
defended the role of the states against suggestions that their power should
be ceded to the commonwealth - on the grounds that federalism produces
increased economic benefits and more stable / effective democracy (with a
built in protection against authoritarianism) [1]
One observer suggested that the establishment of regional governments
would be preferable to centralization as the way to deal with difficulties in
state governments [1].
However, as noted below, if the problems created by centralization within
federal / state relations were reduced, then state governments might emerge as
viable 'regional' governments.
In June 2011 it was noted that states were increasingly resisting the
Commonwealth government and seeking a rejuvenation of the federal system [1]
|
Problems, Possible Solutions and Advantages
|
Problems, Possible Solution and Advantages
Key Problems in Australia's Federal System
There is
no doubt that states have become increasingly ineffectual and virtually irrelevant [1]
-
however that is arguably the problem, not a pointer towards a desirable
solution.
One big problem in Australia's federal system has been that attempts to impose
central government priorities in state functions has increased (mainly because the
states lack independent tax capacity to undertake their constitutional
functions) and this external interference seriously distorts the functioning of state
governments, and contributes to intergovernmental duplication and conflicts.
While this is not the only source of deficiency, fiscal imbalances (which are
more extreme in Australia than in any other federation) have been a
very significant, though generally 'invisible', factor in undermining the
effectiveness of Australia's government and in limiting scope for economic
development (and thereby weakening the tax base relied on for government
revenues).
The first point is explore
in more detail in
Federal State Fiscal Imbalances. The substantial and ever growing
dependence of state administrations on funding derived from federal tax
sources has apparently enforced:
- a centralization of control within state government (ie
placed power in the hands of those dealing with intergovernmental relations at
the expense of those who have have detailed knowledge of what needs to be
done, and how to do it); and
- a political emphasis on lobbying for funding
rather than getting on with the job, which is similar in effect to the
crippling impact that tariff protection had on the effectiveness of management
in Australian manufacturing for most of the 20th century.
This, and a corresponding willingness by states to accept passive dependence
on federal dictates / handouts and on unearned benefits from other sources, has been a significant contribution to making states essentially
incapable of performing, or being held democratically accountable for, their nominal functions.
Moreover, as states have responsibility for governmental effort to promote economic
development (which
function helps determine the overall tax base and thus the total amount of public finances available)
there is a need for them to have appropriate financial incentives. However the federal government
has sought to
ensures that state funding meeds their 'needs' no matter what a states'
tax base, so states have no real incentive to take economic strategy
seriously (see Comment on Review
of Grants Commission Arrangements and
Economic Development Incentives).
Other constraints on the effectiveness of state administrations are outlined,
using Queensland as a representative example, in
The Growing Case
for a Professional Public Service and
Paying the Price
of Ineffectual Public Administration. The latter notes: (a) the lack of strong
civil institutions to provide good quality and up-to-date understanding to the
community about the nature and functions of government (arguably a consequence
of Australia's colonial history and resource dependent economy);
and (b) the damage done to machinery of government by ill-informed political
efforts to improve its performance (such as politicisation, and a consequent
purging of relevant knowledge, skills and experience, and naive attempts to make
governments more 'business-like' in the performance of their often
non-business-like functions).
In the medium to long term, it would appear desirable to adjust revenue
capacity to match the responsibilities of each level of government (so as
to reduce the economic, revenue and administrative costs of current imbalances)
and to ensure that state revenues depended on the wealth created in their
regional economies.
Some writers have suggested imbalances could be resolved if the federal government assumed
responsibility for hospitals (and perhaps other functions) [ 1,
2]. However in any effort to match revenue and spending responsibilities, preference should probably be given to increasing state
revenue capacity (eg by transferring GST and personal income taxes and perhaps
reinstating death duties) rather than increasing federal operational responsibilities. Alternative suggestions
have involved restoring personal income tax power
to states [1].
There is far more to be gained in terms of government efficiency in the
use of resources by enabling state and local governments to be effective,
than there is in attempts by the federal government to optimize resource
allocation Australia-wide in the absence of the information required to do
so and the responsibility for operational outcomes. Coordination of
functions can be achieved without financial control - eg by promoting
collaboration, research into and stakeholder / public understanding of
strategic options and the establishment of
professional standards (eg as promoted by the Standards Association of
Australia in relation to technical issues). In such an environment decentralised decisions in
accordance with locally rational considerations can result in superior
outcomes because: (a) inconsistent actions tend to get smoothed out though a
process that Lindbloom first referred to as 'partisan
mutual adjustment'; and (b) this adjustment process takes account of
vast quantities of local and tacit information that central decision makers
have no way to access. Centralised planning of complex government functions
faces the same fundamental obstacles as centralised economic planning (ie
excluding relevant information / knowledge / experience / initiative and
commitment, and thereby generating solutions that tend to be unrealistic, no
matter how politically popular they are). The
initiative of rational / responsible
individuals
is the primary source of strength in Western societies - but this is
lost where functions are centralised.
A second major problem with Australia's federal system involves the lack of
any constitutional provision to formally and easily adjust the allocation of powers where
this is deemed advantageous. This deficiency leads to constant disputes about powers at the
expense of effective collaboration.
A Possible Constitutional Solution
Quite simple constitutional changes might overcome the above deficiencies. This might involve, for example:
- a constitutional provision that legislative powers not specifically
allocated to the federal government under Section 51 are to reside with the states;
- the creation of an Australia Federal Council through which the states can
delegate state legislative powers to the federal government where they deem it appropriate to do so in the national interest;
- constitutional arrangements that oblige state and federal government to
collaborate (eg making the federal Senate a true state house - with members
appointed directly by state governments);
- a constitutional prohibition on the federal government providing conditional funding to
the states or entering into binding international agreements, except in relation to functions for which the states have
delegated
relevant powers to the federal government or for which the federal government
has power under Section 51; and
- a constitutional provision requiring that the allocation of taxing powers between state
and federal governments must be adjusted periodically so that the revenue
shares of the states and federal government are no more than (say) 5% different from
their share of national public spending associated with their operational
functions - with the Australian Federal Council to determine the
nature of those tax powers.
This would create a system in which: (a) legislative and tax powers would be
retained at the lower level within the federation, but be 'delegated upwards'
when there is a clear benefit in doing so; (b) regional communities would be
obliged to gain familiarity with state, national and international policy issues and
take responsibility for the national interest; and (c) effective collaboration
between federal and state governments would be ensured because the federal
government would be able to exercise power in relation to what were generally
accepted to be national issues, but would be obliged to adopt the role of 'nation
builder' rather than 'national bully'.
Australia does not have a history of successful
referenda to change the constitution - as most fail apparently because the community distrusts efforts to
increase central government powers. Changes along the lines outlined above -
though they would undoubtedly not be adequate in themselves and require more
detailed consideration - would not face this barrier.
The Need for More Than Reform of the Federal System
Such constitutional changes would not in themselves be sufficient to ensure
effective government because, as noted above, difficulties
in federal-state relationships are by no means the only problems faced (see also
Decay of Australian Public Administration, 2002;
Australia's Governance
Crisis, 2003;
Improving Public Sector Performance in Queensland, 2005;
Restoring 'Faith in
Politics', 2006;
The Upper House
Solution: A Commentary, 2006;
Paying the Price of
Ineffectual Public Administration, 2007).
In brief: Pre-existing defects in the capabilities of state governments
related to the 'lucky country's' lack of up-to-date and practical policy support from competent civil institutions were
compounded by (a) significantly increased federal government constraints in the
1970s to exploit fiscal imbalances and (b) politicisation and
distortion of administrative machinery in ill-considered efforts promote public
sector efficiency as a major response to economic challenges in the 1980s and
199os. The
result was serious failures of state administrations (eg consider WA Inc and the
problems experienced by Cain, Greiner and Goss Government). However rather than
dealing with the causes of state failures, the problems in Australia's system of
government were compounded, particularly (but not only) under the Howard
Government, by: (a) increased federal attempts to micro-manage state functions;
and (b) implementing federally the same sort of theoretically-efficiency-seeking
'reforms' that had distorted state government.
Moreover, unless reform is carefully managed, the outcomes are not necessarily
beneficial (eg consider the lessons that emerged from the impractical idealism
of Queensland's
Worst Government).
A Federal System has Important Advantages
Priority needs to be given to reforming, rather than eliminating, Australia's
federal system because (for example):
- community engagement is desirable to reduce the risk of political
instability;
- central control is as ineffective in government as in a market economy;
- diversity is vital to avoid the threat to the existence of simplified
systems which can arise from totally unexpected and disruptive events; and
- Australia's system of government faces many challenges, and can best avoid
the risk of serious failures by building on what currently works (rather than
trying to build idealised 'castles in the air').
Details:
-
community engagement in government is essential to inhibit the development of
political extremism or instability. In many government systems the
principle of 'subsidiarity'
is sought (ie that government functions should be
handled by the lowest / least centralised competent authority) partly to
promote engagement. Moreover:
- community engagement in (and thus understanding of) 'big picture' questions
is vital both to provide an informed electorate, and also to the quality of
leadership that can be provided within the community (see
Queensland's Weak Parliament ). Communities who
are not part of the solution are likely to become the problem (as illustrated
by welfare dependency concerns);
- the
One Nation phenomenon
several years ago provided a warning of the
instability that can result from disengagement. That phenomenon largely
reflected the frustrations of those who were disadvantaged by
centrally-derived policies to promote economic change. Those in
economically-underdeveloped peripheral regions had no way to understand this,
or to cope with the impact on their lives - and so reacted by lashing out
blindly against 'elites' and for a time they proved able to gain a
destabilizingly significant political influence;
- Australia's
federal system is a quirk of history and it is by no means certain state and
territories reflect the optimum level for political engagement about
important social, economic, legal and environmental issues. However, if the
constitution and tax systems were adjusted so that they could be effective,
the inherited system of states and territories might provide a reasonable
compromise as a 'regional' level for government - noting (for example)
Australia's large sparsely populated land mass and the need for reasonable
scale to make any government effective;
- while debates about some political issues are increasingly national in
scope - and in some cases even becoming global, the need for community
engagement in seeking to resolve those issues (and their unique relationship
with other local issues) remains local;
-
centralized control is no more effective in managing the affairs of
government, than in managing an economy. In dealing with very complex
problems, there are no simple 'rational' answers - and a process of discovery
based on decentralized initiative is most effective. The price of this is that
not everyone's solutions are the same (ie not all cars and computers are
identical), but to compensate the best innovations tend to be rapidly copied.
The price of centralization of control based on the 'power of the purse' is
that decisions are separated from those whose tacit knowledge, commitment and
initiative are essential if resources are to be used effectively and
efficiently - and (in effect) the size of the 'purse' is greatly reduced.
These points are illustrated elsewhere in relation to:
- the requirement of s simplified problem space if rational decision making
is to be effective (see Cultural
Foundations of Western Dominance). The strength of Western societies
relies on the effectiveness of individual rationality - though rationality is
widely recognised to fail in dealing with complex situations. The creation of
systems of law and reliance on money in coordination economic transactions
creates simplified problem spaces for individuals, and allows rationality to
work. However the global financial crisis illustrated the failure of
rationality when the role of money became a source of complexity, rather than
simplification, of the decisions individuals needed to make (see
GFC Causes);
- the general corporate shift away from centralised strategic planning in
the 1990s, because the problem was not the development of sophisticated ideas,
but ensuring that ideas matched practical reality and mobilized lower-level commitment (see
Strategy Development in Business and Government, 1997);
- ongoing attempts to centralize control of infrastructure (both within
states and through the creation of 'national' infrastructure programs). The
problem is that infrastructure involves the capital component of some function
and can't sensibly be planned and managed separately from other aspects of
that function (see
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy, 2005 and
Infrastructure
Magic?, 2008);
- 2007 attempts by the present federal government to arrange a new system of
'cooperative federalism' - a rhetorical goal that was defeated by the
imposition of national performance criteria on supposedly liberalized funding
arrangements (see
Federalism: Why 'Control Freaks' Don't Achieve
Real Results, August 2007 and
Australia's New 'Cooperative' Federalism,
December 2007);
- attempts by the present federal government to identify 'the answers' to
what ails Australia through a National Ideas Summit (see
Talkfest Magic?, 2008) and
to fix difficult problems through largely symbolic actions (eg see
Apology
Magic?, 2008;
Productivity Magic?, 2008 and
Public Service
Magic?, 2008);
- there is a need for
coordination amongst different functions on
a regional basis which states (as
Australia's de-facto if not idea regional administrations) should be best positioned to
address;
- proposals for changes in Australia's health system imply strong central
control - and seem to contain serious defects - see
Is
a National Health and Hospitals Network Progress? (March 2010); and
- the currently proposed National Education Curriculum (see
Proposed National History Curriculum: Information
without Understanding?, March 2010)
- diversity is vital to avoid the threat to the existence of simplified
systems which can arise from totally unexpected and disruptive events. For
example:
- monocultures are much more susceptible to catastrophic failures than are
complex ecologies;
- diversity as been recognised to be the defence against (so called) 'black
swan' events.
- Systems that seem stable can be fragile. The banking system is an example
(see The Black Swan). Black swan events are: outside realm of regular
expectations; have extreme impact; and tend to be explained only after the
event. Nature is a complex system with webs of interdependence, non-linearities
and robust ecology - as otherwise it would have blown up long ago. Nature
deals with black swans through redundancies (offering insurance despite
apparent costs). Naive optimization (n the search for apparent efficiency on
the assumption environment is stable) is the reverse. Nature also abhors
anything that is too big - ie at the risk that if one thing fails everything
fails. Only fools thing that it is possible to eliminate randomness from
social / economic life. The challenge is to ensure that mistakes are confined.
(Taleb N 'Song of the black swan', AFR, 16/7/10)
- Australia's system of government
generally faces severe difficulties, and great care is needed to preserve
political stability. Diverse 'modern' challenges to government
effectiveness that have not yet been 'officially' noticed are outlined in
Australia's
Governance Crisis, and unless these are
carefully managed the consequences could be serious. In particular:
- one major risk factor is now
political 'populism'
- which involves gaining political power on the
basis of trendy sounding ideas which are not likely to be effective in
practice. This phenomenon has emerged because the complexity of policy
issues has become too great for simple answers, and the civil institutions
needed to enable the community generally to understand that complexity have
not yet been properly developed. In an environment in which
public
services have been politicised (ie rendered incapable of, and unwilling
to, provide a 'reality check' on 'trendy' policies) the danger that
populist politicians will do a great deal of damage is real. The risk can be
illustrated by the populist claims that a republic could be created in
Australia fairly easily involving a directly elected head of state with
largely ceremonial powers - see
Republican Realism: A Purely
'Ceremonial' Head of State?
- in the face of complex requirements for
change an evolutionary approach which builds on existing institutions is
less likely to generate instability than one that involves eliminating
existing capabilities in the idealistic hope that new and effective systems
can materialize out of thin air. An example of destroying existing
capabilities and then erecting 'castles in the air' that did not prove very
substantial was the 'reform' efforts of Queensland's Goss administration
(see
Queensland's Worst Government?,
2005) .
- Canberra may be unsuitable as a centre
for government. Thus as part of any process to transfer state powers
to the federal government, it might be necessary to shift the latter from
Canberra to a less detached environment (ie Canberra is
physically isolated and primarily involved in government and other
services, which makes it difficult for those who live there to gain 'real
world' information about many issues). The probably need for relocation creates a major obstacle as
Canberra was only developed because neither Sydney nor Melbourne were willing
to allow the other to be the national capital. Indicators of Canberra's
probable limitations include:
- recent suggestions that: (a) there is
a lack of realism in the federal public service and that (b) Canberra is
just a large company town - which is susceptible to problems of 'group think'
(Gottleibsen R.,
Canberra's worse than we thought,
Business Spectator, 25/3/10);
- similar views expressed to the present writer some year ago. For
example: (a) a
Japanese visitor expressed wonder that Australia's national
capital was in Canberra (because he perceived the city to be an artificial
environment, remote from Australia's real economic and social challenges);
and (b) a senior official
in the Prime Minister's Department suggested that people in
Canberra don't live in the same world as most other Australians (ie when
they go to barbecues with friends they encounter one another, but not much
of the 'real' world);
- the Commonwealth has increasingly suffered from the same level of administrative incompetence as the states
because of the adoption of 'quick fix' concepts for reform of
public administration (especially from 2000 on)
(see The Decay of Australian Public Administration);
- the balance of power within a
federation improves political stability - as all levels of government
are unlikely to experience crises simultaneously;
The idealistic assumptions that are the basis for
proposing increased centralization as a quick fix for what ails government in
Australia (while typical) are unfortunately invalid because:
- most of the defects that limit the effectiveness / efficiency of state
governments (with the notable exception of federal interference related to
fiscal imbalances) also apply to Federal Government administration (see
Decay of Australian Public Administration);
- Australia does not have a 'well developed national democratic tradition'
of government but rather an increasingly dysfunctional system in which a loss
of contact with practical reality is increasingly dangerous (eg see
Australia's Governance Crisis). The fact
that the electorate is oblivious to the dangers it faces does not
mean that those dangers don't exist;
- the biggest constraint on effective governance in Australia is the apathy
and ignorance of the general community concerning the nature and functions of
government - a 'Lucky Country' syndrome reflected in carefree expectations of
effortless and inevitable success. Steps to overcome this problem might best involve forcing the community to a greater level of engagement and
responsibility - which requires de-concentration of responsibility; however
- community apathy and ignorance is often amplified by federal government
efforts to micro-manage functions that would otherwise provide regional
communities with opportunities and pressure to improve their awareness and
understanding (see TEQSA: Will
Micromanagement Again Triumph over Government?);
- further increasing the centralization of power is anything but a panacea
(see above). The problem is complexity rather than
the absence of well-intended centralised decision making (see also
Restoring 'Faith in Politics')
However, as Australia's political establishment seem incapable of
understanding that electorally favourable outcomes
can't necessarily be dictated without concern for practical / human constraints, it seems likely that real
progress is only going to be possible after many more failures through policy and program centralisation (such as the 2010 COAG
health and hospital reform arrangement is likely to become - see
Making a Bad Sitution Worse?) |
Addendum A : Moving Beyond Knee-jerk Responses |
On Moving Beyond Knee-jerk 'More Centralism'
Responses (Email sent 12/4/10)
Professor A. J.
Brown,
Griffith Law
School,
Griffith
University
Re:
'Fix the broken wheel of state and give the boot
to the knee-jerk reaction', The
Australian, 10-11/4/10
I should like to
endorse the suggestion in your article that Australians' knee-jerk
'more-centralization' reaction to any problem in government needs
reconsideration, and also to suggest the sorts of changes that might help 'fix
the broken wheel of state'.
In brief it is
suggested (in comments, following this email, in relation to your article and
on a couple of related articles) that:
- problems
affecting state governments are symptoms and examples of broader
often-unexamined challenges facing Australia's system of government;
- Australia not
only has a federal system without a federal culture, but has a democratic
system with only a weak democratic culture. A resulting grass-roots inability
/ unwillingness to take responsibility is the likely source of the knee-jerk
'more centralization' voter response to problems that your survey exposed;
- the
three recent years of intensive efforts to make the federal system work
have arguably been a farce, because of their lack of realistic goals; and
-
the survey conducted on behalf of
your federalism project to determine public attitudes largely reveals
community ignorance - and the parallel between ill-informed community
expectations and the federal government's suspect health and hospital reform
proposal suggests that the latter may be another case of 'populism'.
As far as Australia's federal system specifically is concerned some
preliminary suggestions about constructive directions for reform are in
Fixing
Australia's Federation. The latter also suggests key sources of problems
affecting the the performance of Australia's governments (eg the way in
which federal centralization separates decision making from the people whose
commitment and tacit knowledge are needed for success, and forces states
into equally counter-productive internal centralization).
My draft suggested reforms would be a significant change and be futile
unless other issues raised in
Australia's Governance Crisis were also addressed. However,
unless a serious approach is
taken to the crisis that is now besetting the whole system of
government, the community's welfare is likely to be much reduced in future.
I would be interested in your response to
the above speculations.
John Craig
Outline
of and Comments on Articles
My interpretation
of your article:
The system of government needs
reform, but care is needed in doing so. All sides of politics accept the
need for reform of the federal system. After three years of intensive
efforts to make the federal system work - Australia is up against the limits
of what the present system can deliver. The federal government already has a
pivotal role in driving policy change and controls most of the money. There
is a knee-jerk reaction that the federal government should fix problems. The
federal government's 'funded nationally, run locally' approach to health
reform parallels John Howard's idea of 'aspirational nationalism'. - though
the present PM is not as centralist. But the federal government can't and
shouldn't do everything - as some recent programs demonstrate. In Queensland
there is more confidence in local government - and further strengthening
this may be a key to reform. Because Australians are scattered over a huge
continent they need to be careful what they wish for. The fact that surveys
show that more people think that decisions should be made centrally rather
than at the lowest level is a chilling result. Cheryl Saunders, a global
expert on federalism, has suggested that Australians' tendency to centralism
indicates that we have a federal system without a federal culture.
My interpretation
of related articles by Mike Steketee
4 in 10 voters favour abolishing states as the
least effective level of government. Griffith university's federalism
project conducted survey leading to conclusions that constitutional lawyer
(George Williams) called a crisis of confidence in state governments.
Project director (A. J. Brown, professor of public law) suggests that
states will wither away unless structure of government is changed.
Professor Brown suggested that there were long term structural problems
with the federation. NSW and Queensland suffer worst because of their size
and large cumbersome bureaucracies. Voters agree with PM's approach of
seeking state cooperation on health, but forcing takeover if this fails.
Centralizing government has broad appeal. The federal government is seen
as better at doing its job - though this figure is falling. There is
growing disillusion with government generally. Many voters favour reform
of present system - perhaps to create regional governments. Professor
Williams argued that, though radical reform has support, this could not be
achieved quickly. There is a case for community consultation (or a
convention) on federalism. (Steketee M.,
'Support on the rise to abolish state
governments', The Australian,
10-11/4/10)
Voters want a shake-up in the federal system.
PM's alternating threatening and collaborative approach reflects a deeper
purpose. People want governments to get their heads together to improve
service such as hospitals - and if they can't they want the federal
government to just get on with it. Griffith University's federalism survey
clearly shows this. PM has invested a great deal in cooperative federalism
through participation in COAG. But progress has been slow - and voters are
dissatisfied with states. Though many Liberals used to argue about the
importance of state's right (through inhibiting corruption and promoting
diversity and competition) current Liberal leaders have changed their
view. This does not mean abolition of the states - as constitutional
change to do this would be impossible. However the community favours both
local government and centralization of as many decisions as possible. This
is why the survey fits neatly with Rudd Governments proposals for hospital
reforms - even though increased federal control might not actually improve
the situation. Professor Williams argues that survey results show strong
dissatisfaction with present system - and thus make reform possible -
though this should best be incremental. A starting point would be changes
to the constitution to allow joint federal-state laws and regulatory
authorities. Access economics argues that present federal system wastes up
to 3% of GDP annually (Steketee M.,
'Government should be on the level', The Australian,
10-11/4/10)
In relation to
your article (and the associated reports by Mike Steketee) it is suggested
that:
-
the community is right to be concerned that
Australia's system of government no longer works well. However
problems in state governments seem to be merely symptoms or examples of much
broader difficulties.
Australia's Governance Crisis
(May 2003) was an attempt to deal with the
'bigger picture'. It noted newly-emerging and / or generally-unexamined
problems such as: the difficulties that increased complexity poses for
democratic institutions; the inadequate support to elected governments by
civil institutions; the weakening of governments' administrative support
(due to politicisation of public services and efforts to make governments
act like businesses); a lack of Asia literacy; federal fiscal imbalances;
politicisation of the head of state; and increasing moral policing as the
behavioural standards needed for legal / governance systems that assume
individual liberty have eroded;
- Cheryl Saunders seems correct in suggesting
(as you noted) that Australia has a federal system without a federal culture.
However the problem is broader - as Australia apparently has a
democratic system without a strong democratic culture. Australians
do does not 'own' their system of government (ie the present system was
inherited as a product of Australia's colonial heritage). Moreover the
community suffers a 'lucky country' syndrome (ie believes that it is entitled
to effortless success). Reliance has traditionally been placed on external
investors in natural resources to ensure wealth and on government to share it
around. However in the community there is little realistic understanding of
the nature and functions of government, and little commitment to supporting
the institutions needed to gain such understanding - and this facilitates
abuses of power and political success with poor policies (see
More Competent External Support to Parliament). As merely copying reforms
made earlier in UK / US ceased to be automatic over the past few decades, a
huge amount of damage has been done by pursuing ill-informed initiatives
dreamed up by inexperienced idealists (see
Decay of Australian Public Administration,
November 2002);
- what you described as the three recent
years of intensive efforts to make the federal system work have likewise been
a farce, because:
- those efforts seemed like just more of the
same centralization of decision making and impractical / idealized 'reform'
that has been crippling governments for decades. The effect of practical
defects (eg fiscal imbalances / enforced centralization within state
governments / public service politicisation and inappropriate
'business-like' methods) were not addressed (see
Federalism: Why 'Control Freaks' Don't Achieve
Real Results, August 2007);
-
the current federal government tried to
promote federal-state collaboration by a focus on a populist, but
impractical policy agenda (see
Australia's
New 'Cooperative' Federalism,
November 2007). While constructive organisational development can be
achieved by presenting a 'vision' of a new arrangement that practitioners
can commit to, this can't be expected from endeavours to enforce
insubstantial political rhetoric;
-
the 'populist' rather than realistic
policy basis for promoting cooperative federalism is a symptom of the weak
institutional support mentioned above. Earlier experience
associated with Queensland's Goss Government showed that going through the
motions of 'reform' on the basis of a half-baked policy agenda can be
disastrous - by creating organisations that merely have to pretend to be
effective (see
Queensland's Worst Government?,
January 2005);
-
the survey conducted on
behalf of your federalism project to determine public attitudes to the federal
system largely reflects community ignorance. That survey showed dis-satisfaction
with government generally (states in particular) and a growing view that
reform is needed. However because of the lack of analysis or public awareness
of the causes of problems in Australia's system of government, voter responses
are not a reliable guide to anything except getting votes. If, as Mike
Stekette
implied, current proposals for health and hospital reforms would confer
political advantage (because they parallel uninformed voter preferences)
without necessarily resulting in real improvement (see also
Is
a National Health and Hospitals Network Progress?,
March 2010), then those reforms
are likely to be another example of the dangerous trend towards
populism
which besets Australia's political system
|
Addendum B: Re-imagining the Federation to Develop New Cities +
|
Re-imagining the Federation to Develop New Cities
(email sent 6/7/10)
George
Megalogenis
The Australia
Re:
'States the only tier that could deliver the
goods, yet they are not up to it',
The Australian 5/7/10
As your article
suggested, reinventing Australia's federation is vital to grow the new cities
needed to accommodate ongoing population growth with less congestion. But this
is only part of the challenge.
My
interpretation of your article:
Australia needs another city
if population and living standards are to rise, yet this won't happen
unless we re-imagine the federation. The job is too big for one tier of
government. The thinking / spending logically falls to Canberra, yet
implementation remains with states. But they aren't equipped to do this,
because default response to city congestion is to extend existing
metropolitan boundaries. Existing cities could hold many more people, but
governments don't want to put their name to high density developments.
Thus can towns (eg Townsville) be turned into cities?.
No matter where growth zones are selected, states can't be constructive
partners because federation created the perverse incentive for states to
run services badly so as to get top-up funding from Canberra. To break
this cycle requires states to see themselves as planners, not service
providers - and this requires that planning ministers have central roles.
The first government able to refocus growth will deserve the compliment of
nation builder.
The key to developing new cities is to avoid the
temptation to just plan infrastructure and real estate - as the latter is
equivalent to the building of phoney airfields by cargo-cultists in New
Guinea in the hope of enticing aircraft to land and unload 'cargo'. Rather
there is a need to focus first on the development of productive economic
functions in regional centres so as to create high-wage jobs as strong
'magnets' for population growth, while tax reform is needed to motivate
state governments to allow this to be achieved. Infrastructure and real
estate must be provided efficiently in response to population growth, but
they are secondary issues.
As your article correctly noted fiscal
imbalances in Australia's federal system are a serious obstacle to any
effective contribution by state governments, because the latter are not left
with any ability to take real responsibility, or be held democratically
accountable, for their nominal functions. This obstacle is artificial and
could be overcome by a review of Australia's tax system to more closely
balance revenue sources with responsibilities - as suggested in
Fixing Australia's Federation (2010).
However the
problem is not just that the deficiency in the quantity of tax revenues that
are available to states undermines their efficiency and effectiveness. The
nature of the tax sources that states have available means that, though they
are the level of government with primary responsibility for economic
development, they have no financial motivation to encourage the growth of new
high value-added economic functions that might attract population growth.
State tax revenues tend to relate to the volume of economic transactions,
rather than to the value added - and this means that the types of economic
activities they are motivated to encourage are often not those in the best
interests of the community. Once again this artificial obstacle could
overcome (see
Providing Incentives for Effective Economic
Development, 2009).
Techniques are
available to accelerate the development of high value-added economic functions
through stimulating market-oriented 'learning' within regional industry
clusters - eg as suggested in
Developing a Regional Industry Cluster (2000). This
would achieve better results than traditional techniques for reasons
outlined in
A Case for Innovative Economic Leadership (2009).
The main reason that better results could be achieved (and thus create
population magnets to turn regional centres into major cities) would be that
development would be responsive to 'market-pull' rather than 'political push'.
There are solid reasons to suggest that economic development can not be
successfully led by politically accountable organisations (see
Economic solutions are beyond politics,
1995). Experiments conducted with the use of these alternative methods in the
late 1980s, before Queensland's public service was politicised and de-skilled
by the Goss administration, showed promising results.
As the process
suggested above requires true 'nation building' (eg empowering others to
achieve results by defining the protocols under which others would 'do things'
that are market-responsive), there is a need for states to have a financial
motive to value success in the development of productive economic
opportunities more than the popularity they believe they gain by being seen to
'do things' themselves. Current financial arrangements in Australia's
federation are counterproductive, as states are compensated for the weak tax
bases that result if they do not take economic development seriously (see
Review of Grants Commission Arrangements
, 2001).
Developing new
cities would be much easier if federal and state political leaders took a real
interest in building the nation, rather than always striving to be seen to
control outcomes themselves (eg by building 'things' for
the nation).
John Craig
Reinventing the Regions - email
sent 8/10/10
Professor Sandra
Harding,
Vice Chancellor,
James Cook
University
Re:
Reinventing the Regions,
The Australian, 15/9/10
I should like,
belatedly, to try to add value to your constructive suggestions about
improving the image and prospects of rural and regional Australia.
My
interpretation of your article: Regional Australia has won
from the 2010 federal election - including $500m for regional education.
However in considering a cash injection it is important not to miss the
historic opportunity of securing vibrancy in rural and regional Australia
(which requires more than money). The key is a change of mind. Without
this, efforts to enliven regions / regional education will be shallow. It
is wrong to assume that high quality institutions and economically
productive / culturally satisfying life is only available in cities. Other
advanced economies don't assume this. Australia is held back by extreme
urbanisation and negative views of regions. In US, Britain Europe non
metropolitan regions can be excellent - but in Australia this is not so.
The question is, is Australia serious about nation building - or simply
placating sectional interests? But the backlash is on - with (laughable)
talk of inequity for metropolitan areas / regions. The time is right to
build vibrant regional economies - as Menzies Government understood in the
past, and Queensland government understands now. There is a need to shift
urban population to rural and regional Australia. While new infrastructure
is welcome, there is a need for much more. There must be vibrant regional
economies - and these won't exist without quality higher education
delivering human capital and innovation directly into regional
communities. But while quality education is needed, NBN also
offers brilliant prospects of raising ambitions for 21st century. It will
affect where businesses locate and people live. The NBN offers greatest
prospect to de-urbanise - to relieve pressure on cities. Regional
Australia should get NBN first to provide competitive advantage. But NBN,
regional education, health, economic and social development (while needed)
are just planks which mean little without a change of mind. But some don't
see this - because they live in shadow of extreme urbanisation (as in
Plato's cave). Australia needs to come out of the shadows, and this can't
happen until Australia comes out of shadows also. There is a need for true
nation building
By way of background let me make clear that I have
some knowledge of, and sympathy for, the challenge of development in north
Queensland. While working for the then Coordinator General's Department in
1973, I was the first (though only acting) Regional Coordinator for north
Queensland, and supported local groups (including those from James Cook
University) in producing a preliminary study of the region's prospects and
problems. I note also that I wrote the first substantial report on how
Queensland might develop its capacity as a 'smart state' while working for the
then Premier's Department in 1983.
In relation to the issues you raised it is
suggested for your consideration that:
-
your article is quite correct in noting that, to
boost rural and regional prospects: (a) there is a need for more than cash
injections; (b) many different elements are needed (eg communications,
education, health etc); but little will happen unless these 'planks'
are bought together into a cohesive whole. Development theorists
often advocated the provision of 'missing strategic factors', and it was
then found that whatever 'strategic factor' was provided was wasted, because
of the lack of complementary assets. For example, education was often
emphasised and produced a brain drain (because of the lack of job
opportunities for the better educated). Similarly efforts to provide 'smart'
inputs (eg research and education) into Australia's economy in the hope of
generating 'smart industries' have tended to fail, because nothing effective
was done to increase the commercial ability of the economy generally to use
those inputs productively (see
Commentary on 'Smart State',
2003 and
The Economic Futility of 'Backing Australia's
Ability 2', 2004);
-
the key requirement for drawing the various
'planks' of regional development together into a cohesive and dynamic whole
is not a change of community or political minds. Rather it is to create the
capacity in the region to meet market demand for goods and services in
competition with the world's best - and thus start attracting
people to the region by providing good job prospects. Regional
development can be accelerated by 'market pull' (because it requires and
encourages different entities in a region to integrate their efforts), but
won't be sustainable if it is only supported by 'political push' on various
poorly-related inputs;.
-
some suggestions about how such economic
capabilities can be 'bootstrapped' are in
Re-imagining the Federation to Develop New
Cities. In simplest terms this
involves a process that encourages accelerated 'learning' about new market /
technological opportunities within an embryonic industry cluster.
Information is well recognised by economists as the key factor in economic
growth, and it is most powerful if used as a way of motivating and enabling
changes in economic systems. Such a process can't be effective if undertaken
through politically accountable entities. Thus changes in the financial
incentives facing state governments are suggested, so that states might
enable progress to be achieved in spite of the political benefits they gain
from trying to control outcomes (and thus taking away the 'market pull' that
could make resulting actions sustainable). It can be noted that supporting
such processes can potentially be VERY profitable for those with strategic
land holdings - because the value of land tends to be a function of the
incomes of the people and businesses nearby. Some years ago it was guess-timated
that a $50m investment by a major property developer over 25 years could
yield a $5-10bn increase in the value of their residual land holdings;
-
if a 'natural' (ie market driven) population
'magnet' can be created in a regional centre, then there are
feedback effects associated with what can be called 'migration industries'
(ie the provision of support services for the people who start to move to
the region) who will accelerate this process (see
Towards
Effective Management of Both Growth and Development).
Such feedback effects
clearly
had a major impact on population growth in SE Queensland - ie migration to
the region stimulated initially by low taxes and a sun-state phenomenon
created large numbers of job opportunities, which in turn attracted further
migration;
-
there are now structural obstacles to
the further growth of Australia's major cities which will tend to
make it easier to attract migration to well developed rural and regional
areas. A key example involves transport, where it is clear that significant
problems have emerged in developing viable strategies (eg see
Brisbane's Transportation Monster, 2008).
Urban footprints have been defined for major cities on environmental
grounds, and this makes it impossible to access the cheap rights of way
required for freeway-based transport systems (which are traditionally
associated with urban sprawl). However urban densities in Australia's cities
are not sufficient to support good mass transit systems, and attempts to
boost urban densities have proven problematic. If viable transport systems
can not be created, the amenity / attractiveness of cities relative to other
locations will be severely affected. Similar constraints on the amenity of
major urban centres are arising from the rapidly increasing cost of
utilities;
-
a process of 'nation building' is now
needed which goes well beyond the sorts of changes that would enable rural
and regional Australia to become better developed (see
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for
Nation Building). Australians' bias
towards major cities is complemented by a bias towards central authorities
as the source of solutions to their problems and the source of
opportunities. Reversing both biases is needed to build a strong and
prosperous nation in Australia.
Thus the question is: is Townsville and North
Queensland serious about wanting a vibrant rural and regional Australia? Such
outcomes should be achievable though accessing information about available
opportunities and stimulating networks of local entities to consider mutually
reinforcing initiatives to address them - without creating dependency on
political decisions or government support. The latter must be a later stage
in the process.
I would be
interested in your response to the above
speculations.
John Craig
|
Addendum C: More Statesmanship: Less Politics |
Addendum C: More Statesmanship: Less Politics
(email sent 2/9/10)
Professor Judith
Sloan,
Institute of
Applied Economic and Social Research,
University of
Melbourne
Re:
'Stronger states the key to wealth',
The Australian, 31/8/10
I should like to
try to add value to your useful suggestions about reinvigorating Australia's
state governments.
My interpretation
of your article: Towards the end of the 2010 election campaign, the
Prime Minister implored voters to distinguish between state governments and
her government - as she wanted her positive economic plan not to be ignored
because of concern for poorly performing state governments. But at the same
time she (and the Opposition) mainly focused election promises on what the
community would expect from state governments. A Victorian Premier once
accurately predicted that the time would come when the federal government
would be blamed for everything. Recent developments reflect the final stage
of a long trend towards trashing the principles that underpin Australia's
federation. The Rudd Government undermined federalism in the name of ending
the blame game and a seamless national economy. Ending the blame game
involved maximum possible centralisation of functions - or setting complex
bureaucratic rules to force states to comply with targets set by Canberra in
exchange for funds (as was the case for the health and hospital reform
package - which is now increasingly being criticised). Similarly, business
concerns about reducing the burden of differences in state regulations
resulted in the creation of unworkable mechanisms through COAG. The latter
has had some successes (eg with occupational health and safety laws), but
most of its working parties are now largely defunct. WA premier argues that
they merely resulted in duplication and confusion. Even more serious is that
costs of regulatory differences were grossly overstated - as competitive
federalism always acted to favour improved regulation and minimize
differences. Similarly mining taxes reflect further confusion about
federalism. Arguing that all Australians deserve to benefit from mineral
wealth overlooks the fact that, under the Grants Commission, adjustments are
made to federal grants where states gain substantial mineral revenues.
Present system actually penalises states for efforts they might make to
improve tax regimes. When first established, federal government was expected
to have functions that apply to the whole country, and that the states would
remain autonomous. However the federation is now in trouble because of
ambitious / misguided federal politicians, gross vertical fiscal imbalances
and a centralising High Court. Experience shows that federal systems produce
better economic outcomes than unitary states. Thus there is a need to reform
Australia's federal system so as to reinvigorate state governments.
Your article noted that the poor performance
of state governments (who are mainly ALP controlled) led the Prime Minister to
fear that her government might be punished in the recent federal election. It
seems that this may have happened, and (if so) it would have been partly
deserved. Administrative and political distortions, resulting from decades of
manipulation of state functions by successive federal governments, are
arguably the main (though not the only) cause of ineffectual state government
(see Fixing
Australia's Federation, March 2010). The latter offers some speculations
about how this particular problem might be reduced. It also mentions the need
for stronger external and internal support to state political systems, as well
as changes to operating arrangements and very careful management of
reform. Related reforms to make Australia's system of government generally
more effective are speculated in
Australia's Governance Crisis (from
2003).
However difficult reforms requires statesmanship
(ie a commitment to reform of dysfunctional systems, rather than merely
seeking political popularity by exploiting them), and there is little sign of
this amongst Australia's current political leaders.
Even an independent MP who reportedly claimed an
intention to ''... support the party or parties that ... will deliver stable,
competent and ethical government " (Nadar C.,
Wilkie may yet reject all suitors , 31/8/10) seems to believe that a key
characteristic of such a reformed system of government would be
generous federal handouts to his electorate. As some of these handouts seem
to require micro-managing state functions, federal compliance with such
demands would presumably make the effective provision of public services and
economic development much less likely.
Seeking State Pork
in the Federal Barrel: "The 22 demands set out by Wilkie, the new
Denison MP, show how difficult the task [of effective government] will be.
In March, Wilkie stood for Denison at the Tasmanian state election and won
8 per cent of the vote. At the federal election he won 21 per cent, taking
votes equally from the Liberals and the Greens. One reason was that this
time he had a new issue, telling southern Tasmanians they were not getting
their fair share of federal funding because they were in safe Labor seats.
So, naturally, his wish list yesterday began with 10 local demands,
starting with a new Royal Hobart Hospital, and including funding for
broadband, roads, public transport, including a light rail for Hobart's
northern suburbs, and a demand that the government withdraw its formal
approval of the proposed Gunns pulp mill. Then there are 12 broader issues
..... (Colebatch T.,
'A climate for change', 31/8/10 )
Despite such discouragement, your efforts in
advocating fundamental reforms to make Australia's system of government
workable are to be applauded, because in 5-10 years the need for change may
have been accepted in the community sufficiently for political leaders to
respond.
In conclusion, I note that brief comments on
various other issues that were mentioned in your article follow this email.
John Craig
SOME
COMMENTS ON OTHER ISSUES MENTIONED
Centralization
Centralised
strategic planning, which was widely adopted by major corporations as the best
way to respond to rapidly changing conditions, had largely been abandoned by
them by the late 1980s - because it proved unable to mobilize the knowledge,
experience and commitment of those not at the centre any more than central
economic planning could do (see
Strategy Development in Business and
Government -
1997). However this constraint seems to have escaped the
attention of many advocates of public sector 'reform' in Australia.
Emerging criticism of health and hospital
reforms.
This reform package seems likely to have made
a bad situation worse, because
unworkable administrative arrangements have been established (eg trying to
manage hospital services by fixing 'efficient prices'). The failure of Soviet
economic models in the USSR showed that activities can't be effectively
controlled by administratively-determined prices.
Well established nationwide sharing of
mining revenues by the Grants Commission
The RSPT proposal seemed to suffer other defects
which have not yet gained public recognition (see
RSPT won't hurt miners: But pity help naive
Australians ). The latter suggested
that a lack of Asia-literacy by policy makers risked adversely impacting
Australia's total mining-related tax revenues.
Penalization of state initiatives by the
Grants Commission
Arrangements for revenue sharing under an
overly-centralised federal system also seriously limit Australia's economic
prosperity, because: (a) states have the lead role in governmental efforts to
catalyse economic development, but (b) they have no financial incentive to
take that responsibility seriously - because of: (a) the narrow tax base they
have available; and (b) Grant's Commission formulas that compensate them if
they fail to create the strong tax base that a well developed economy would
provide (see Economic
development incentives).
|
Addendum D: Infrastructure: A Big Picture View |
Infrastructure: A Big Picture View -
email sent 16/4/12
Glenda Korporaal,
The Australian, 7/4/12
Re:
Where there's a bill there's a way, The Australian, 7/4/12
Your article identified Australia’s serious problem in
providing infrastructure. However the solutions advocated by the sources you
have quoted do not seem to reflect a ‘big picture’ understanding of either: (a)
why problems exist; or (b) what might be done to manage infrastructure
development more effectively.
My interpretation of your article:
Australia’s capitals need major transport projects that states can’t pay for.
Infrastructure NSW chairman (Nick Greiner) says states no longer have the
operating surpluses needed for big new infrastructure projects. NSW Government
is under budgetary pressure, Queensland is having its financial problems
assessed and Commonwealth is seeking to eliminate a $40bn deficit. Greiner
identified two options: (a) asset recycling; or (b) private funding. COAG report
on why cities are not progressing rapidly will be released soon. Cities generate
75% of jobs, and 80% of economic output. Strategic planning for capital cities
is at a watershed due to: population growth; increasing energy costs; and shift
to a knowledge economy. Report suggests further work is needed on: improving
freight transport and intermodal networks to support port / airports; more
public transport emphasis; and integrating transport / land use decisions. While
there is general agreement on the need for better infrastructure, federal and
state governments have not agreed on what is needed – and states periodically
change their priorities and can disagree with Infrastructure Australia which
seeks to prioritise major infrastructure projects nationally. Infrastructure
Australia examine projects put forward by states in four categories (ie it
classifies them as: early stage; real potential, threshold; and ready to
proceed). Infrastructure Australia seeks to make cities work better and more
efficiently (especially in terms of roads, rail, and freight). Lists of
potential projects are available. Infrastructure Partnerships (Brendan Lyon)
suggests that there is general agreement on the need to fund these – and
governments will need to reorganise their budgets to do so. This could require
asset sales, and introducing competition into government service delivery to cut
costs. They will need to consider what assets they hold, and privatisation. Lyon
suggests that NSW and Queensland consider sale of remaining electricity assets
to fund new projects (eg for mass transit, completion of Pacific Highway upgrade
and efficient freight connections). The private sector will need to be involved,
but has been burned by big losses on tunnels.
It is submitted for your consideration that:
- Effective infrastructure development does not require
lists of ‘major’ projects for federal funding, but rather the development of
functionally specialised government agencies that are competent and supported
in identifying, resourcing and implementing large numbers of major and minor
projects that are the capital component of the public functions they
are dealing with;
- Australia’s machinery for developing infrastructure is
highly dysfunctional due (for example) to federal fiscal imbalances, and
attempts over the past couple of decades to apply commercial / competitive
methods to functions that are subject to serious market failures;
- Lists of major projects put forward by entities such as
Infrastructure Australia should be questioned because: (a) such proposals have
typically emerged from apparently dysfunctional machinery; (b) claims about
the need for urban infrastructure seem to be overstated; and (c) centralised
strategic ‘planning’ passed its use-by date many years ago; and
- While there is a need to work out how infrastructure is
financed, the issues involved go well beyond options such as asset recycling
and increasing private financing. For example, there is probably a need to:
strengthen the tax base by a more serious approach to economic development;
and recognise that private infrastructure financing does not actually increase
available resources.
These points are developed further on my web-site.
John Craig
DETAILS
Infrastructure in Context
Infrastructure involves the capital components of basic systems that are
needed for a society and economy to operate (ie the capital components of systems
for transport / water
supply / sewage / electricity / telecommunications / flood mitigation / etc).
Much infrastructure is best provided by government because it involves
functions that
are subject to market failures, which make it impossible to provide those
systems satisfactorily on a
purely commercial basis through a competitive market (eg because of the
existence of externalities / monopolies, or the lack of appropriate pricing mechanisms,
or the need to manage large complex networks as a whole). And
those capital components are related in many ways to other regulatory
and ongoing operational aspects of those public functions, and of other government
responsibilities.
It makes no more sense to separate the capital components of
functions that are legitimately-public responsibility into ‘projects’ that can be chosen by central planners than
would be the case for (say) the shops traditionally required by retailers.
Likewise it makes no sense to deal with 'major' elements of infrastructure
systems whose usefulness depends on many complementary 'minor' investments.
What
is needed for effective public infrastructure development is not a list of major
projects, but rather functionally specialised, responsive and democratically
accountable government agencies that are
competent and supported in identifying, resourcing and
implementing large numbers of major and minor capital projects on an ongoing
basis while: (a) also undertaking
non-capital
aspects of those functions; and (b) managing the relationship with other
functions (eg see
Focusing on projects is a bad way of developing infrastructure or the public
sector).
Dysfunctional Machinery
Australia’s machinery for the planning and development of
infrastructure is highly dysfunctional as a result of both long term distortions
in the federal system and of efforts over the past two decades to
improve efficiency by applying commercial and market mechanisms without
really considering the effect that this would have on government effectiveness
generally, or the effect of commercial / competitive arrangements on
functions subject to serious market failures.
An attempt to outline these
structural defects is in
Infrastructure Constraints on Australia's Economy (2005). The latter
referred to;
- Numerous factors that seem to have contributed to problems in
infrastructure development in the case of Queensland with which the present
writer is most familiar. This included:
- the inability of states to take proper responsibility for their
functions or deal with them effectively that results from Australia's massive federal fiscal imbalances.
Federal financial control encourages: (a) centralisation of control within states
that separates decision making from those with the detailed knowledge and
experience required to make good decisions; and (b) a focus on lobbying for funding, rather than on what needs to be
done (which is similar to the predicament that manufacturers faced when
their viability depended on tariff protection);
- fragmentation of responsibility for particular infrastructure
systems as a result of seeking competitive /
commercial methods since the early 1990s;
- loss of human capital from government machinery (as a result of politicisation
of 'senior' positions, which ensured the dominance of 'yes men');
- unrealistic attempts at centralized
strategic planning;
- Queensland's ‘corporatisation’ approach to government enterprises;
- privatisation of a monopoly; and
- Commonwealth attempts at central planning.
- the complexities generated by public-private partnerships which:
(a) add costs in contract management that offset expected operational efficiency gains;
(b) create problems in dealing with integrated infrastructure systems as a
whole; and (c) risk distorting / corrupting the political process because of
self-interested lobbying which the agencies that support governments may be
unable to counteract because they lose
access to the necessary information;
- the diversity of constraints on Australia’s economic productivity
all of which need attention, and of which infrastructure is only one component;
- constraints on infrastructure financing (see further
below).
Inadequate Infrastructure Proposals
While there are undoubtedly lists of projects that have
been submitted to, or developed by, Infrastructure Australia (or Infrastructure
NSW) there are many reasons to doubt the adequacy of such lists, because:
- the existing machinery for developing such project proposals seems
highly defective (for reasons suggested above),
and has a history of fiascos.
Many problems have arisen in infrastructure development in Queensland
such as those briefly mentioned in
A Dysfunctional and Difficult Environment.
For example the Queensland Government apparently endorsed the Traveston Dam proposal
to boost SE Queensland’s water supplies after a brief desk-top study though
there seemed to be technical reasons to doubt its viability. Queensland's premier
then publicly committed to the project
'whether or not it was feasible'. And hundreds of millions of
dollars were wasted before the project was scrapped - nominally on
environmental grounds (see
Evaluating Additional Water Supplies in SE Queensland).
- the perceived need for, and cost of constructing, major urban
infrastructure projects may well be much greater than necessary –
because:
- tunnels have routinely been developed to complete links in the
freeway networks in major cities – and often proved financially disastrous. Freeway-based transport systems require
cheap rights of way that can only be available if urban sprawl is tolerated. For
valid environmental reasons Australia’s
cities have adopted urban footprints and have thus limited access to cheap rights of way.
This (combined with likely future escalation in fuel prices and
the fact that tunnelled freeways apparently cost some 5-7 times as much as surface routes) arguably makes
freeway-based transport systems inappropriate as a significant component of future
urban transport systems (see
Brisbane's Transportation Monster, 2008). And, because population densities
are too low for the development of effective public transport
alternatives, Australia’s existing major cities face perhaps-insoluble
constraints on their future growth;
- Options exist to boost economically viable regional development,
and thus to limit the concentration of population growth in existing cities (eg
see
Reinventing the Regions);
- high rates of immigration both: (a) creates a need for massive infrastructure investment; and (b)
escalates construction costs by contributing to
labour shortages and thus raising wage rates (see
Developing Australia's Economy: The Role of Migration, 2010 – which refers
to the high labour demand generated by ‘migration industries’). Given problems in financing infrastructure
(see below) and skilled labour shortages, reducing migration perhaps needs to
be considered as a way to moderate those
pressures;
- Strategic ‘planning’ (the method apparently expected to be used by
bodies such as Infrastructure Australia) is an inappropriate way to identify
infrastructure options. The notion of strategic ‘planning’ by central staffs was
perceived in the 1970s as enabling organisations to decide strategy in the face
of a complex, changing environment. However it had apparently been rejected by major
corporations by the 1990s (in favour of strategic ‘management’ which basically involves
leaders
posing strategic questions for others to answer) because of the inability of
central strategic ‘planners’ to acquire the information and commitment required
to make appropriate decisions (see
Strategy Development in Business and Government , 1997).
Financing
While there is a need to work out how infrastructure
can be financed, the issues involved go well beyond just considering asset
recycling (ie privatising some existing infrastructure to free up capital) and
encouraging private financing. For
example:
- Australia’s grossly unbalanced federal fiscal regime not only makes it
essentially impossible for states to effectively undertake their nominal
functions (as noted above), but
also provides them with no incentive to take economic development (and thus
the creation of the strong tax base needed to finance infrastructure and
other public goods and services)
seriously – see Economic development
incentives;
-
states lack the capacity to fund the infrastructure they
are expected to provide. This can be illustrated by concerns expressed
about NSW (see above) and about Western Australia's situation (Taylor
P.,
Opposition rises in the now-flat boom state, The Australian,
7/4/12) and by Queensland's apparently more dire
predicament (see
Recovering from Queensland's Debt Binge). The latter
also demonstrates that limited state revenue constrains infrastructure
funding (eg only a fraction of its revenues can be increased
by state decisions about taxes and charges);
- through private involvement (eg on contract) in the development of
genuinely public infrastructure can be highly advantageous, private funding does
really not provide additional resources because
it
will always depend on user pays arrangements. Similar additional resources
could be mobilized by governments, if the latter were also prepared to adopt
a user-pays philosophy. Moreover, private financing and control of parts of infrastructure systems creates
complexities that offset likely production efficiency gains (as noted
above).
Conclusion
Overcoming current problems primarily requires seeking effective organisational and funding systems
whereby
infrastructure needs can be identified, financed and implemented. It is not
sufficient to simply apply a band-aid over dysfunctional machinery by encouraging
Infrastructure Australia (and similar bodies) to make lists of 'major' projects
for federal funding.
|
Addendum E: Infrastructure's New Road |
Infrastructure's New Road - Email sent 11/5/12
Professor Ken Wiltshire,
University of Queensland
Re: ‘Let’s
get infrastructure on the right road’, Australian Financial Review,
9/5/12
While there is no doubt that Australia’s machinery for dealing with
infrastructure needs renewal, the challenge seems more complex your article
suggests.
My
interpretation of your article:
It has been uneconomic for the private sector to fund infrastructure because of
Australia’s low densities, and the public’s desire for equal standards
everywhere. Thus government was responsible for infrastructure in 1901, and the
states engaged in wasteful competition while accumulating large debts. The Loan
Council was then created to facilitate federal takeover of state debts.
Australia is the only federation with a constitutional base for infrastructure
coordination. But the Loan Council lapsed. Infrastructure lags 10-15 years
behind what is required. Thus there is a need for a new approach.Infrastructure
Australia has done good work, especially on infrastructure funding. But it is a
Commonwealth body. States must be at the table. The constitutional provision for
the Loan Council should be used as Infrastructure Australia’s legislative base.
This would allow: (a) addressing regulatory inconsistencies; (b) assessment of
projects on a national basis; (c) applying transparent / evidence-based public
policy principles; (d) analysis of horizontal fiscal equality formula for GST;
and (e) embracing and eliminating problems with PPPs (eg problems such as:
excessive bidding costs, poor governance, imprecise risk sharing and poor
dispute resolution). There is a need to consider why governments should
undertake activities that the private sector is willing to undertake.
My reasons for suggesting the need for reform to go down a different road are
outlined in
Infrastructure: A Big Picture View. In brief this suggests that: (a)
infrastructure that involves true public goods and services (ie functions
subject to serious market failures) can’t realistically be assessed as
‘projects’ on a national basis separated from the other aspects of the public
functions of which they are the capital components; and (b) private ownership of
elements of such infrastructure is likely to create serious problems.
Some
specific comments on issues raised in your article are outlined on my
website. These suggest, for example, that:
- problems with the private ownership of infrastructure functions that are
subject to significant market failures were recognised in the UK in the mid 19th
century. This resulted in machinery of government reforms that led to the
system that Australia inherited, and abandoning this is now allowing those
problems to re-emerge;
- those problems relate to the complex relationship between much
infrastructure and other functions of government, as well as the potential for
corruption;
- while governments have again run up excessive debts as Loan Council
discipline was lost, discipline is also needed in accounting standards,
because abuses have apparently emerged from the use of pseudo-commercial
methods;
- Infrastructure Australia’s efforts (ie to identify needs and suggest ways
of financing these as separable projects) have failed to address the real
problems in infrastructure planning and delivery;
- the 10-15 year lag in infrastructure provision across Australia is the
result of decades of poor government; and
- reforms to allow governments and infrastructure investment to be effective
must go well beyond establishing Infrastructure Australia under the Loan
Council’s constitutional provisions.
I would be interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
Detailed Comments
In relation to the issues raised in the article it
is suggested that:
- Public investment in infrastructure has not simply been a consequence of
(say) low population densities. The major reason that Australia's governments
initially took responsibility for infrastructure was arguably that problems
with private ownership and control under official patronage had been
recognised in the 19th century in the UK (from where
Australia’s institutions were copied) and reforms to address those problems
had been a goal of the Northcote-Trevelyan report of 1854 which was seen to
have been effective in “removing corruption, delivering
public services (even under the stress of two world wars), and responding
effectively to political change” because it had resulted in the
creation of a professional / apolitical public service (see
Her Majesty’s Civil Service, Wikipedia);
- Problems with private ownership of elements of infrastructure functions
that are subject to serious market failures were suggested in
Public-Private Partnerships for Infrastructure (2002). The latter referred
to:
- the inevitable
complexity of such infrastructure which causes contract management and
regulatory costs to escalate to offset likely efficiency gains from private
provision; and
- the difficulties of maintaining enough technical competence and
information in government agencies to maintain control of the agenda and the
consequent
potential for corruption of government.
- There is undoubtedly a need for disciple in relation to public finance,
like that the Loan Council used to provide. States (notably Queensland) have
again indulged in wasteful spending and run up huge debts (eg see
Recovering from Queensland's Debt Binge). However the problem is not only
the loss of borrowing discipline that the Loan Council had provided, but also
that the adoption of pseudo-commercial accounting methods permitted creative
accounting that has apparently misrepresented the state’s financial
obligations. New discipline in defining accounting standards is urgently
needed;
- efforts by Infrastructure Australia (ie to identify infrastructure
needs and devise means for financing these as separable ‘projects’) have
largely been a waste of time, because: (a) central planning is no more
likely to be effective for government investments that have complex
interactions with related functions than is the case for activities within the
market economy; and (b) nothing has apparently been done to address the real
institutional and financial obstacles to the effective provision of
infrastructure;
- Based on Queensland’s experience, it seems likely that the current
10-15 year lag in infrastructure provision is the result of decades of poor
government (see
Defects in Infrastructure Planning and Delivery in Queensland , 2002).
This referred, for example, to:
- the escalation of Commonwealth special purpose funding in the 1970s that
largely deprived states of the ability to take responsibility for their
nominal functions, and distorted their machinery of government (eg by
requiring unrealistic centralisation and more focus on lobbying for funding
than on effective provision of goods and services);
- the shift in the 1980s away from a systematic approach to government, as
emphasis was given rather to supporting private investors' major projects to
exploit the state’s natural assets;
- the breakdown of effective machinery of government in the early 1990s
that resulted from politicisation, purging of accumulated knowledge and
experience, fragmentation of responsibility and attempts to apply
business-like methods in undertaking primarily non-business-like functions;
- While there is a need for states to be at the table in terms of making
decisions about the future of government functions, it would not be
sufficient to do this through a revamped Infrastructure Australia which sought
to plan and facilitating private investment in major infrastructure projects
(while operating under the Loan Council’s constitutional provisions).
Rather what is probably needed is an arrangement that allows the
rationalisation of government functions and revenues between levels of
government to both: (a) eliminate the distortions associated with extreme
fiscal imbalances; and (b) facilitate coordination. Suggestions that an
Australian Federal Council might allow these goals to be achieved are in
Fixing Australia's Federation (2010);
- Much more than reform of Australia federal system is needed to allow
government to become effective (eg as suggested in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the
Need for Nation Building (2003+). The latter referred, for example, to:
(a) better support to the political system; (b) more effective approaches to
economic development to promote economic growth and a strong tax base that is
not dependent on commodity booms and busts; (c) coping with a (possible) 'Asia
century'; and (d) ensuring the continued viability of liberal legal and
governance institutions;
- There certainly is a need to consider why governments should be
undertaking functions that the private sector would be willing and able to
undertake. The privatisation of various government assets in Queensland
was undertaken some years ago without any apparent evaluation of whether this
was desirable - under circumstances in which conflicts of interest seemed to
be a very real risk (see
About the 2009-10 Budget).
|
Addendum F: Loss for Federal Government |
Loss for Federal Government - email
sent 22/6/12
Bernard Keane
Crikey
Re:
Chaplains outcome another belated loss for the Howard govt, Crikey,
21/6/12
Might I respectfully suggest that the
constraint that the High Court imposed on the federal government in relation to
spending on functions that it does not have a legislative basis for, is as much
a belated loss for the Whitlam Government (which escalated the use of special
purpose federal funding in the 1970s) as it is for the Howard Government.
There are two reasons to suspect that
legal constraints are now likely to be imposed on the federal government’s
capacity to spend on whatever it likes.
The first is that the financial capacity
to provide funding for popular new programs is evaporating (eg see
Australia's Federal Budget Surplus?). When there is no money to buy votes,
federal governments are likely to welcome High Court decisions that constrain
their ability to do so.
The second is that the distortion of Australia’s machinery
of government (and the constraints on a serious approach to economic
development) associated with Australia’s world-beating level of federal fiscal
imbalance is also likely to be increasingly seen to be unaffordable from now on
(see
Fixing Australia's Federation, 2010 and
Economic development incentives, 2009).
John Craig
|
Addendum G: Centralization is Part of the Problem: Not the Solution |
Centralization is Part of the Problem: Not the Solution - email sent 1/1/13
Troy Bramston
The Australian
Re:
'Scrap states' to drive reform: Bob Hawke, The Australian, 1/1/13
Your article quoted suggestions by a former
Australian prime minister (Bob Hawke) that increasingly centralized governance
(by scrapping state governments) would expedite necessary reforms. This
unfortunately does not reflect any realistic understanding of the greater
benefits that societies such as Australia can potentially gain by doing more to
facilitate competitive / collaborative decentralized initiative.
My interpretation of your article:
Bob Hawke has called for abolition of
the states in the interests of achieving more effective government. He expressed
concern about being unable to get agreement on a national land rights framework
because of WA government opposition. Australia’s system of government is now the
result of the way it was explored 200 years ago – and would not be what would
exist if established now. Mr Hawke also urged business and unions to work more
closely with governments, and pointed to the need to educate the public on the
merits of reform.
The strength of societies such as
Australia, which have a Western cultural heritage, lies in the ability of
individuals in various community / business / administrative contexts to
mobilize the power of ‘rationality’ (ie the use of abstract concepts as models
of reality) to make incremental rational decisions which taken together generate
solutions to a society’s social, economic and governance challenges (see
Cultural Foundations of Western Strength in Competing Civilizations,
2001+). For example, a market economy is preferred to a centrally planned
economy because of the limits to rationality facing central authorities (eg
their inability to acquire all the information needed for appropriate decisions
and to ensure the commitment of others to their decisions). Similar constraints
lead to recognition in management literature about the limits to centralized
decision making, and the role of decentralized incremental initiative. And
public administration literature makes frequent reference to the
counter-productive outcomes that well-meant policies sometime suffer because the
complexities of the social and economic systems involved were not appreciated
(eg consider
the effect of land rights on isolating many Australians with indigenous
ancestry from the opportunities that others enjoy and exposing them even more
than the general community to the ‘curse’ of rich natural resources).
Whether Australia’s state governments are
geographically or functionally optimal is an open question. However the naïve
belief that centralizing control of all government functions (rather than (say)
ensuring that states can be effective in undertaking their constitutional
functions) has contributed to making government complex, ineffective and
excessively costly (see
Federal-State Fiscal Imbalances in Australia’s Governance Crisis,
2003+).
There are moreover other reasons to suspect
that increased reliance on decentralized incremental initiative would be more
constructive than reliance on the limited rationality of central decision
makers. For example:
- the issues that governments have to deal with are
becoming increasingly complex (and thus less amenable to simple solutions), and
the ability of governments to deal with complexity has simultaneously been
eroded (eg by politicisation of public services which means that governments
tend now to be supported by ‘yes men’, rather than by broad knowledge and
experience) – see
Challenges to Democratic Institutions;
- economic constraints are causing fiscal
difficulties for governments in meeting ever-rising demands for social spending
while also providing infrastructure. Modern democratic government emerged in
Britain in the 19th century (and was transported to Australia) partly
as a means for
sharing the wealth generated by capital in industrial economies. Generating
wealth that has been ever-increasingly challenging for decades (eg due to the
boom-bust character of industries involving exports of basic commodities, tough
international competition, the need to shift to knowledge-intensive industries,
environmental constraints, and international financial instabilities). And
taxing wealth has become harder due to the effect of economic globalization.
Moreover limits are increasingly emerging in: (a) boosting economic productivity
by traditional methods for economic reform (eg those based on market
liberalization); and stimulating growth with counter-cyclical fiscal or monetary
policies. Alternatives are available (see
Lifting Productivity: Considering the Bigger Picture, 2010),
but these require that governments focus on ‘governing’ (ie enabling
collaborative initiatives by others) rather than just on the things that they
directly control.
Some undoubtedly-inadequate suggestions
about mobilizing competitive / collaborative decentralized initiative to reduce the problems
in Australia’s federal system that concern Mr Hawke are outlined in
Fixing Australia's Federation (2010), while broader
suggestions about achieving more effective government are in
Australia's Governance Crisis and the Need for Nation Building (2003+).
John Craig
|
Addendum H: Major Budget Savings or a More Complex and Expensive Public
Sector? |
Major Budget Savings or a More Complex and Expensive Public Sector? - email sent 7/2/13
Robert Gottleibsen
Business Spectator
Re:
Super tax backdown PM's only choice, Business Spectator, 6/2/13
Your article suggested that, in relation to resolving structural budget
difficulties facing the federal government, the Opposition will be able to
“raise large sums by rationalising state and federal activities” and in the
process “actually improve services’.
There is no doubt that there is a huge potential to benefit by eliminating the
current duplication, complexity and cost of Australia’s government operations
(see
Federal Fiscal Imbalances). However the Opposition’s
Real Solutions for All Australians plan does not clearly specify what is
intended, and risks making a bad situation worse because of an apparent failure
to understand the nature of the problem.
The Opposition’s plan refers (for example) to:
- Getting “spending down by fixing the overlap between different levels of
government and reducing the size of the bloated Commonwealth payroll” (p17);
- “delivering a more effective and responsible public services focused on your
needs” (p17);
- “unleash the real economic potential of our education and research sector”
(p30);
- Delivering modern infrastructure (eg by developing a 15 year plan for national
infrastructure projects; empowering Infrastructure Australia to ensure better
value for money; and encouraging more private investment in infrastructure)
(p31);
- Delivering major roads and highways (p32), and better local roads (p35);
- Building more dams to provide water security (p32);
- Improving cooperation with state governments through COAG (p38);
- Improving local hospital performance (p39);
- Improving the local performance of schools (eg by encouraging schools to become
independent, ensuring a rigorous curriculum, continuing current funding,
increasing science investment, reducing red-tape, ensuring stable infrastructure
funding) (p40);
- Improving housing affordability in collaboration with the states (p40);
- Establishing a national safe streets program (p42);
- Developing land in northern Australia (p42).
This mainly involves the Opposition (as a future federal government) using its
fast-fading ‘power of the purse’ to continue trying to undertake / control
spending on functions for which states and territories have the constitutional /
legal / operational responsibility.
State / territory functions can’t be disentangled from their administration by
making operational functions (eg schools, hospitals, roads, water supplies,
housing and land development) into notionally separate entities that can be
directly funded / regulated by the federal government.
The primary function of government is ‘governing’ (ie creating a regulatory
framework in which others can do things) and ‘doing things’ (such as providing
schools, hospitals, etc) involves functions that are subject to: (a) market
failures; and (b) diverse regulatory / policy consideration which always involve
interaction and thus a need for administrative coordination with other aspects
of state / territory administration.
Without completely rewriting the constitution this obstacle can’t be overcome –
so what seems to be being proposed would simply add to the complexity, red tape,
duplication and cost of public functions by continuing to:
- Enforce centralization of control within state / territory administrations (in
the hands of those dealing with financial affairs and intergovernmental
relations) which ensures that decision / control is taken out of the hands of
those with the greatest policy / operational understanding and experience (see
Federal Fiscal Imbalances);
- Suppress collaborative decentralised initiative (see
Centralization is Part of the Problem: Not the Solution);
- encourage state / territory governments to focus
on lobbying for funding (as the managers of manufacturing firms were
encouraged to focus on, rather than customer demand, in the days of heavy
tariff protection);
- provide no incentive for states / territories to
develop strong tax bases by taking economic development seriously.
The Opposition’s goal is to be applauded – but its proposed method of
implementation seems impractical. An alternative approach to eliminating the
duplication, complexity and cost associated with current federal / state
problems is outlined in
Fixing Australia's Federation (2010). This suggests, for example, that
- The focus should be on ensuring that all levels of government have their own
financial resources appropriate to their responsibilities – and promoting
competencies and collaboration within such a fiscal framework;
- Canberra would probably not be a suitable location for Australia’s national
capital if it were expected to take primary responsibility for operational
government functions – because of its remoteness; and
- Rather than encouraging Infrastructure Australia to make a list of, and seek to
control, major ‘projects’ (all of which would have complex policy and practical
entanglements with other state / territory considerations) it would be better
employed finding ways to fix the mess that has been created in the machinery for
planning and developing infrastructure over the past 2 decades (see
Infrastructure: A Big Picture View, 2012).
I would be
interested in your response to my speculations.
John Craig
|
Fixing Australia's Federation for Economic and Well as Public
Administration Benefits |
Fixing Australia's Federation for Economic and Well as Public Administration Benefits - email sent 22/8/13
Andrew Lynch and Shipra Chordia
University of NSW
Re:
Federal-state reform: is Abbott offering the real deal?,
The Conversation, 21/8/13
Your article questioned whether the federal
opposition was genuine in offering a new approach to Commonwealth State
relations by clarifying the ‘responsibilities so that
each level of government, as far as possible, is sovereign in its own sphere’,
given that Mr Abbott’s 2009 book (Battlelines) had suggested that
“the only way to sort out responsibilities in areas
where the two levels of government are both involved is to put one level of
government in overall charge.’
Might I respectfully suggest that the only
way to genuinely create a workable federal system (one that is not plagued by
the duplication, buck passing, uncertainty, pork barreling and unnecessary costs
of Australia’s present arrangements) is through reform of the taxation system
(ie to end the extreme federal fiscal imbalances that create the impression that
the federal government needs to have the dominant role in what could otherwise
be state functions). Some suggestions about this are in
Fixing Australia's Federation
(2010). The latter referred not only to the prospect of better
public administration, but also to giving states a financial incentive to take
economic development seriously and thus both aid economic adjustment to the end
of the China boom and provide a stronger tax base to reduce governments’ fiscal
difficulties.
John Craig
|
The Politics of Reforming
Australia's Federation |
The Politics of Reforming Australia's Federation - email sent 25/4/15
Professor Andrew Lynch,
University of Western Sydney
Re: Federalism
at stake if $4b is cut from schools and hospitals, The Conversation,
24/4/15
I should like
to try to add value to your suggestion in this article that the Federal
treasurer seems to be alienating the states, rather than mobilizing their
support, in efforts to reform Australia’s federal system. It is possible
(though by no means certain) that there is method in that apparent madness.
Tax revenues
and spending responsibilities within Australia’s federal system are extremely
unbalanced (ie as your article noted the federal governments gets 80% of revenue
and transfers about 25% of this to the states because the latter’s own-revenue
sources are well below their spending responsibilities). This fiscal imbalance
generates severe distortions in the provision of public goods and services (for
reasons suggested in Federal
Fiscal Imbalances, 2003+).
Those distortions could be reduced if states’ own-source revenues were roughly
equal to their spending obligations. And the fact that most state revenues are
currently provided on a ‘needs’ basis through the Grants Commission gives
the states no financial incentive to take economic development seriously (ie to
develop a strong tax base and thus to maximize government revenues overall).
States, who have most influence on economic development, derive a great deal of
revenues from particular types of economic turnover (which they thus have
financial incentives to maximize by the types of economic functions they
encourage) but very little of their direct revenue depends on the economic value
added that would do most to maximize government revenues overall (as well as
increasing household incomes and business profits). There should be considerable
benefits in terms of strengthening Australia’s economy (and thus the tax base)
if state taxes were not as narrowly based as they have been (see
Economic
development incentives, 2009).
However there
is a political obstacle to such reforms.
For decades
states have gained political credit for providing public goods and services that
they do not pay the political cost of collecting taxes to finance. Thus states
have little enthusiasm for eliminating Australia’s federal fiscal imbalances.
And, in the past, federal governments also benefited politically from those
imbalances – because federal ministers could announce popular increases in
spending and be directly identified with the outcomes through special purpose
federal programs.
Now, however,
the game is changing. There are likely to be severe structural difficulties in
generating sufficient tax revenues to provide the goods, services and transfers
that the Australian community expects (for reasons outlined in
A
Broader Approach to Tax Reform,
2015). Thus federal governments can’t be expected to have any enthusiasm for
struggling to raise taxes merely to enable state governments to gain political
applause from spending them.
Rather the
federal government can be expected to favour states gaining broader tax powers
so that they bear the political cost of struggling to raise the revenue their
functions require in the much more difficult environment that is emerging.
However, for the same reason, the states can be expected to resist any such
reform for as long as they can. Tightening the fiscal noose on the states, as
your article points out that the federal government is doing, may be the only
way to get them to be serious about negotiating a new arrangement. And, as
your article noted, the federal government seems to see changes in federal
financial relationships as complementing its white paper on tax reform.
Though the
fiscal pressures the federal government is applying to the states are
ham-fisted, it is possible that they may have a serious purpose.
John Craig
|
The Need to Rethink Malcolm
Turnbull’s New Strategy to Unlock the North |
The Need to Rethink Malcolm Turnbull’s New Strategy to Unlock the North - email sent 12/1/16
David Crowe,
The Australian
Re: ‘Malcolm
Turnbull’s new strategy to unlock the north’, The
Australian, 6/1/15
Your article referred to the federal government’s proposal to
stimulate development in northern Australia primarily by providing financial
support for large scale infrastructure and resource projects. While this would
presumably lead to the growth of some economic activities, such an approach is
likely to restrict and distort the real development of northern Australia.
Enhancing the economically-relevant knowledge and capabilities of people in
larger existing north Australian communities would be a better option, as this
would start a sustainable process of locally-initiated growth and development
for which public sector support would be provided through normal government
machinery.
My Interpretation of your article: The federal government has widened the scope of its $5bn
plan to spur new growth across northern Australia. This involves loan guarantees
for major infrastructure and resource projects. This is expected to boost
investment in the north in the aftermath of the mining boom. Debt guarantees are
under consideration and draft legislation will be available soon. Northern
Australia has only 1.2m people but makes up half the land mass, generates $178bn
economic output and is expected to grow faster than the rest of Australia.
Investments in transport, mining, energy and agriculture could be encouraged.
Loan applications could be taken from mid-2016 – on condition that private
funding accounts for 50% of any project. Long term capital would be
provided by government. Applicants are likely to seek funding for: an airport; a
rail line; a waterfront precinct; a dam; roads; and water storages. Tony Makin
(Griffith University) said government loans would be a form of ‘industry
assistance’ / ‘picking winners’ that would have budget risks. Sinclair
Davidson (RMIT) warned against industry assistance for projects that were not
commercial – and that governments should not carry out private sector tasks.
Gary Gray (Opposition resources spokesman) said that projects would need to
satisfy public benefit test – not just marginal electorate benefits
As your article noted, economists have warned that the proposed
arrangement could result in government funds being directed to ‘assist’
projects that would not be particularly economically beneficial. In
response to this Richard Holden (University of NSW) argued (in Turnbull
needs community of believers for northern growth’, The Australian,
11/1/16) that the provision of government loan guarantees for infrastructure
would not be a misguided form of ‘industry assistance’ because:
- Australia is verging on ‘secular stagnation’ and (as
economists worldwide are now recognising) there is thus a need for public
investment to counter this, as the ability of monetary policy to provide an
economic stimulus is now limited; and
- Businesses are not going to invest in relatively underdeveloped
regions unless they are convinced that a lot of other people are likely to do so
– as otherwise the support services they require won’t be established. The
proposed government loan guarantees might provide a reason for a large number of
businesses to conclude that the plan will succeed, and thus significantly
increase the regional development impact of government efforts through their own
investments and activities.
Both of these observations seem valid. There is indeed a risk
that government funds could be misused (ie ‘pushed’ for electoral gain into
projects for which real market demand is limited; or co-opted to primarily
benefit private interests with good political connections). And, as Richard
Holden suggested, there is a need for many support functions to attract large
scale business investment in northern Australia.
However creation of a federal government fund to help finance
major infrastructure and resource projects in northern Australia would not be
the best way to go about this.
Why: Resource
rich regions such as northern Australia are usually
economically
‘cursed’
(ie remain relatively backward economically) because they attract external
investment in their natural comparative advantages (ie resources) which have
little to do with (and do little or nothing to enhance) the competitive
advantages of the regions’ people and businesses. Political and business
elites support such investment because they themselves profit (politically or
commercially) from doing so. However by doing so they provide very poor economic
leadership to affected regional communities.
The
current scheme would require those who propose infrastructure or resource
investments to lobby the federal government (ie central planners) for funding.
History suggests that this can make it hard for them to meet real needs. When
tariff protection was seen as the key to developing manufacturing industry,
lobbying government was more important to manufacturers’ success than
developing competitive advantages in meeting customers’ demands. And the
ongoing need for states to give priority to lobbying for federal funding is a
major cause of the difficulties they have in the efficient / effective provision
of the public goods and services that are their constitutional responsibilities
(see Federal
Fiscal Imbalances, 2003+).
The
proposed ‘strategy to unlock the north’ might attract investment in north
Australia’s comparative (ie natural) advantages that outsiders control and
benefit from, but do very little to: (a) create regional industrial clusters
with strong competitive advantages; (b) start a sustainable process of
locally-initiated growth and development; and (c) attract large numbers of
migrants to north Australia with high levels of skills and income prospects.
Much more could be achieved by boosting, in north Australia’s
larger centres: (a) knowledge of market and technological opportunities;
and (b) the commercial competencies and organisation that are required to take
advantage of them. This might not result initially in the sorts of
‘grand’ projects that are currently envisaged to receive government
financial support, but it would really develop north Australia.
Some suggestions about how market-driven progress might be
accelerated were outlined in Reinventing
the Regions (2010). As noted in the latter there are limits to ‘missing
strategic factor’ theories of regional development. A very large number of
ingredients must be in the mix and must be developed in such a way as they can
operate as an integrated whole. However emphasising one missing strategic factor
(eg infrastructure) and doing nothing to stimulate the development and
integration of all the others means that much of what is spent on the favoured
‘missing strategic factor’ is likely to be wasted.
The economic futility of responding to lobby groups
who can provide 'missing strategic factors' (without a primary emphasis on
creating an economy that can use them productively) can be illustrated by the
reported inability of highly qualified individuals (in Australia and Canada) to
gain appropriate employment [1]
There is little doubt that Australia (probably) faces ‘secular
stagnation’ because of: (a) the ending of the resources and housing investment
booms; (b) China’s
financial, economic and political vulnerabilities; (c)
potential
global crises linked to ultra-high debt levels that have been incurred in
recent years to sustain growth; and (d) the apparent
ending
of easy money policies as a viable means for macroeconomic stimulation.
Thus very significant domestic efforts are needed create a sustainable
path for Australia’s economic and employment growth. However, even though
those efforts might include fiscal stimulus:
- simply encouraging the development of one of northern
Australia’s ‘missing strategic factors’ (ie infrastructure) would probably
be a waste of time and effort. Moreover (for reasons suggested
here)
infrastructure investments especially in northern Australia probably now
require serious consideration from a security viewpoint. Potential economic
benefits can’t be the only (or perhaps even the main) criteria in evaluating
such investments;
- sustainable and productive development of north Australia
primarily requires introducing strategic economic information and commercial
competences into its major communities, so that competitive advantages and the
seeds of economic leadership of balanced development can emerge from within the
region itself;
- there would be a huge potential to enhance Australia’s economic
performance by reform of the machinery by which economic affairs are managed (eg
see Broken
Governance and Ineffectual Economic Strategy: Two Sides of the Same Coin?);
- there is a need to revisit issues that the G20 put into the
‘too hard’ basket after the start of the GFC to deal with the international
structural incompatibilities that are largely (though not solely) responsible
for the world’s emerging stagnation and crises (see
G20:
Peace for our Time'?, 2009).
John Craig
|
Developing the North for the
Benefit of Australians |
Developing the North for the Benefit of Australians - email sent 31/3/16
Senator the Hon Matthew Canavan,
Minister for Northern Development
Re: Lets
develop northern Australia for the benefit of us all, The Australian,
30/3/16
There is no doubt about the benefit to all Australians of
genuinely developing northern Australia. However the most effective /
beneficial way to achieve this may not be the massive government funding of
infrastructure / industrial investment that your article mentioned. A
better approach would probably involve building on, and building up, the
‘competitive advantages’ that north Queensland’s existing population
already has, or could create.
My
Interpretation of your article: A
great deal can be achieved in times of crisis (eg developing the Hann Highway
during WW2). That route could now be upgraded under the federal government’s
proposed North Australia Roads Program. Northern Australia lacks infrastructure
not opportunities. It receives 60% of Australia’s rainfall, involves 40% of
the land and produces 55% of exports. 6% of Australians live in northern
Australia and the region produces 11% of national GDP. Nationally full time
employees produce about $186,000 of economic output annually. In the north
full time employees average $370,000. It makes sense to reinvest in regions that
are already making money. This is why the government has a $6.2bn plan for
northern Australia (eg for roads; water resources). Support would also be
provided for: R&D; changing land tenures; investing in tropical medicine. A
bill to establish $5bn concessional loan facility for north Australia (that
would be subject to strict controls / conditions) was introduced last week in
conjunction with Resources Minister (Josh Frydenberg). Growing north Australia
will benefit all Australians – as 80% of taxes flow to Canberra. Developing
wealth will best position Australia relative to Asia where 2/3 of world’s
middle class will live. The government’s white paper on development of
northern Australia is the first ever. Australians should support it no matter
where they live.
Your article argued that the federal government should
provide several $bn for new infrastructure and to subsidise industrial
investment in northern Australia because: (a) north Australia produces 55% of
Australia’s exports; (b) the region produces 11% of GDP though it only has 6%
of Australia’s population; (c) average GDP per full-time employee for
Australia as a whole is $186,000 while in north Australia it is $370,000; and
(d) there are many economic opportunities in the region. It also referred to
investing in R&D and industries where north Australia has technological
strengths (eg tropical medicine).
However this argument is a bit simplistic because:
- The major opportunities in northern Australia that could be
supported by infrastructure or industrial investment are likely to be those
involving exploitation of the region’s natural resources;
- Exports based on exploiting rich natural resources were long the
basis of Australia’s reputation as a ‘Lucky Country’ (ie Australians
enjoyed a good living standard despite the nation’s comparatively
under-developed economy). However Australian’s ‘luck’ was steading
running out during the first 8 decades of the 20th century. National
GDP / capita was in constant decline by international standards;
- That decline was the reason that efforts were made to diversify
Australia’s economy from the 1980s through various economic reform initiatives
(which largely involved market liberalization). A desire to shift from
exploiting ‘comparative’ advantages (ie the pre-existing characteristics of
a region) to developing ‘competitive’ advantages (ie those associated with
knowledge / skills / strategy) was a hoped-for consequence of those reforms. In
part this reflected new economic understandings at that time about the need
(usually but not always) to develop ‘competitive’ advantages if a region’s
/ nation’s industries are to support high income levels (see
Creating
Competitive Advantage, 1994);
- Competitive advantages in knowledge and skill related activities
won’t be achieved by government investment in R&D and related industries
in northern Australia. Rather creating the capacity to benefit economically from
innovation primarily requires building up commercial competencies and organisation – ie a region’s ability to turn ideas into
new or more successful
businesses (see Australia
is Still Not Serious About Developing Its Innovation Systems, 2016);
- Natural resource-related industries have long tended to be:
- associated with relatively underdeveloped and low income economies
(see Curse
of Natural Resources, 2001). Rich resources can lead to poor economic
leadership by local political / business elites if they: personally gain
political / profit benefits from collaborating with investors in a region’s
‘comparative’ advantages; and thus don’t explore options to develop
‘competitive’ advantages that would better advance the economic prospects of
their communities as a whole;
- subject to extreme boom-bust cycles – a fact which recent
history demonstrates yet again. A ‘stronger for longer’ hypothesis
(involving the presumed end of commodity boom / bust cycles because no limits
were seen to the growth of demand from China and other emerging economies) was
put forward in Australia a few years ago, but was predictably invalid (see
Do
Blind Spots Cloud the RBA's 'Lucky Country' Vision?, 2011);
- The high current contribution to GDP from north Australia is
largely derived from capital intensive resource-related industries – ie from
exploiting the region’s ‘comparative advantages’. However while such
industries’ and north Australia’s contribution to GDP is high, their
contribution to GNI (gross national income) is significantly lower. Much of the
income that derives from highly capital-intensive operations flows to (often
offshore) investors. Australia’s GDP has recently been rising by (about) 2.5%
pa – but GNI (gross national income) has been declining. And it is GNI that
determines what Australians actually earn – and thus their ability to
stimulate the economy by their spending as consumers.
Some speculations about a potentially better approach to
accelerating the economic development of north Australia in ways that would be
in Australians’ interest are outlined in The
Need to Rethink Malcolm Turnbull’s New Strategy to Unlock the North .
Those speculations suggest that the ‘competitive’ advantages of north
Australia’s population should be emphasised in driving economic growth and
development, rather than continuing to emphasise ‘comparative’ advantages.
Information is the key factor in economic growth and development. Boosting north
Australians' ability to access market and technological intelligence and turn
this into economic opportunities will achieve more than pouring $bs of
taxpayers’ money into infrastructure and subsidies for industrial investment
on the assumption that the ‘stronger for longer’ theory (ie that
resource exports will be Australia’s best economic option over the next 2-3
decades) is valid.
This does not imply that natural resources would not play a
role in north Australia’s development. However it does mean that the
importance of building north Australians’ ability to play important roles in
initiating / organising those, or any other, economic activities should be
emphasised. Also there is no implication that infrastructure would not play a
part in north Australia’s development. There will be situations where
infrastructure is justified by: (a) the ‘national interest’; or (b) current
populations and economic opportunities. However it does imply that governments
are unwise to ‘pick economic winners’.
John Craig
|
A Financial Wedge to Start the Reform of Australia's Federal System?
|
A Financial Wedge to Start the Reform of Australia's Federal System? - email sent 1/4/16
Hon Mr Malcolm Turnbull, MP
Prime Minister of Australia
Re: Owens J., and Lewis R., States
taxing power a fundamental federation reform, Turnbull says, The
Australian, 30/3/16
You reportedly argued that reform of Australia’s
federation is needed - and that this could be started by changing the tax system
to allow states / territories to access some income-tax revenues. I would like
to suggest why there could be large fiscal and economic benefits from increasing
and broadening state / territory revenue sources, and also draw attention to the
need for much more than changes to tax arrangements to achieve effective reform
of the federal system.
My
Interpretation of the above article in which you were quoted: Malcolm
Turnbull announced plans to provide states and territories with independent
income tax powers – suggesting this would be the most fundamental reform to
the federation in generations. He saw this as the only way to address the
vertical fiscal imbalance that is at heart of the failure of Australia’s
federation. The Commonwealth would reduce income taxes to some degree and allow
states to levy income tax at a rate they choose. In a federation state citizens
should determine how much revenue their state government raises. States have
traditionally demanded federal funds for underperforming functions, rather than
raising state levies / charges. They have not had any other tax bases to raise
money – and one will now be provided. It would be important to ensure that the
system did not disadvantage smaller states. The failure at the heart of
Australia’s federation is that states lack access to revenue sources. Mr
Turnbull argued that his proposal would end the blame game / arguments /
duplication. The move would not be about increasing total taxes, and the ATO
would raise all income taxes. Opposition spokesman, Chris Bowen, suggested the
proposal would result in mangled system / higher and more complex taxes – even
though government had promised lower / simper taxes. Greens leader (Richard Di
Natale) labeled the proposal a ‘cop out’ (by dumping problems on states /
territories) to avoid hard decision on federal taxes. State are divided on the
proposal. Private sector observers offered both support and cautions about the
proposal.
I should like to support your reported suggestion that
vertical fiscal imbalances (ie state responsibility for most spending while the
federal government has most revenue sources) has been a major cause of the
problems that have beset Australia’s federation. The effect (eg
irresponsibility, buck passing, duplication and complexity) has been most
serious in undertaking public functions where the federal government has come to
provide special-purpose funding (see
Federal
Fiscal Imbalances, 2003).
The distortions generated by vertical fiscal imbalances
have had non-trivial, but hard to quantify, costs. Offsetting the cost of those
distortions has been the federal government’s ability to use its ‘power of
the purse’ to promote ‘national’ programs to address issues for which the
federal government sometimes has had no constitutional authority. But that
benefit is unlikely to exceed its costs because:
- Federal governments (and the national political process) have come
to be expected to take the lead in dealing with ‘everything’ – because,
until the GFC and the ending of the huge capital gains
derived from resource investment boom, their revenues used to grow sufficiently to meet all perceived
needs. However that expectation (and the political
appeal to federal governments of taking financial responsibility for
'everything') now seems to be unsustainable without
significant reforms (see Restoring
the Viability of Democratic Capitalism, 2014). For example, overcoming
governments’ fiscal challenges arguably: (a) requires changes to boost the
effectiveness / competence of government machinery; and (b) faces obstacles
because of problems in the international economic environment (see
The
Challenge and Potential Cost of Inequality and Insufficient Income). Amongst
other things the latter refers to structural
incompatibilities amongst various different systems of socio-political-economy
that lead to international financial imbalances and
credit
constraints on global economic growth because of rising debt levels
(constraints that also arguably apply to Australia because of
escalating
dependence on borrowing to drive economic growth);
- The effective development of Australia’s economy (and thus of
the tax base) has been impeded by existing federal financial arrangements.
States have more influence on specifically what economic capabilities are
encouraged in various regions than the federal government does. However the tax
sources available to them have mainly been based on ‘economic turnover’,
rather than on economic ‘value added’. Thus states have not had strong
financial incentives to take the development of high value-added economic
activities seriously – even though emphasising value added would have done
most to maximize wages, corporate profits and federal taxes (see
Economic
Development Incentives, 2009). The present writer had a decade-long
involvement in issues related to the development of Queensland’s economy
during the 1980s (see CV) and
found progress to be impeded at that time by that state’s Treasury’s
emphasis on maximizing the state’s narrow tax revenue sources. States
have also been discouraged from serious attention to the requirements of
developing high value-added economies by the fact that large components of their
revenues have come from the federal government on a ‘needs’ basis (ie under
Grants Commission procedures) rather than as a consequence of the performance of
their regional economies;
- Australia inherited Western-style political, administrative and
economic institutions. Their strength lies in creating scope for incremental
rational initiatives by diverse organisations / individuals to respond to the
emerging problems and opportunities that they perceive – initiatives that
others then observe, copy and improve upon. The centralized financial control
that is implicit in Australia’s world-champion vertical fiscal imbalances
(which is comparable in the sphere of government to central economic planning)
has arguably been a major obstacle to Australia’s overall ability to respond
quickly and appropriately to emerging problems and opportunities that affect
government functions (see
Centralization,
2003 and Centralization
is Part of the Problem: Not the Solution, 2013); and
- Large financial imbalances give states / territories strong
financial incentives to emphasise lobbying the federal government for finance
rather than focusing on ‘their job’ (see Reducing
the Adverse Effect of Vertical Fiscal Imbalances on Government Administration,
2009). This has had much the same distorting effect as heavy reliance on tariff
protection used to have on manufacturers (ie requiring them to focus on lobbying
governments rather than on their markets' changing demands).
The present writer’s experience / study of methods for
coordination in government suggest that action to address ‘national’
aspirations could be promoted without the distortions associated with primary
reliance on the centralized financial controls that large vertical fiscal
imbalances allow.
Action to address the massive problems that fiscal
imbalances (and the nature of states’ revenue sources) pose for the
effectiveness of government in Australia is long overdue. Your suggestions might
provide a way to start a reform process. However even transferring some
income-tax revenues and greater responsibility for (say) health and education to
states / territories will be a disaster unless attention is given to enhancing
their competence in dealing with such issues. The need to overcome the
competency problems that have developed in recent decades is illustrated
here.
Some suggestions about what reform of the federation might require in addition
to changed tax arrangements are outlined in Fixing
Australia's Federation (2010+).
John Craig
Response from a Contact
with Experience in Public Administration in Queensland
"Some 50 years ago one of the main tasks of staff of the
Queensland Audit Office was ensuring that Commonwealth funds for the
health system, $2 per
patient day stay in hospital , that were being claimed were
legitimate.
This checking had to be done physically in every hospital
in Queensland . A specific accounting program was approved by
the Queensland Health Dept to
make sure that all was correct and done more efficiently.
Hospitals are also still apparently spending large amounts of
money to ensure their share of the cake.
Many many other certified statements covering other aspects eg
drought relief had to be supplied to the Commonwealth.
It was certainly a paper war.
State Treasury was always trying to maximize the cash flow from the
Commonwealth as funds were always very scarce. The surmise is that
it is still happening.
The costs to Queensland of doing all this exceeded the return on
a cash basis but no effort was known to have been made to measure
the economic costs. This type of problem is thought to have
escalated since so it is right to go for efficiency now.
The matter of Australian states being able to raise taxes through
the Commonwealth system seems logical If one goes for
accountability by state administrations as against the
current system of handouts. However the business sector will be very
happy as it enables it to
play games with the States by locating business operations
physically in the state that gives the best deal similar to what
goes on in America now.
It is understood from press reports that Queensland’s
premier just paid out millions to attract an ethanol plant
to the state that was likely to have located here anyhow. This is
the type of problem that will emerge.
Politically a number of prime ministers have stumbled with this
problem – Rudd, Gillard, Abbott.
No party is immune.
Will be interesting to see who wins this one eventually. It’s a
high risk strategy anytime and bigger just prior to an election."
|
Reducing Congestion by Accelerating the Growth of Australia's Second-tier
Cities |
Reducing Congestion by Accelerating the Growth of Australia's Second-tier Cities - email sent 14/1/17
James Pearson
Australian Chamber of Commerce and Industry
Re: Second-tier
cities key to unclogging our future, The Australian, 13/1/17
I should like to endorse your suggestion about the
potential benefits of strengthening Australia’s second-tier cities. However to
achieve this, improving a regional community’s access to and ability to use
strategic information to attract migration will be better than (say) public
investment in land and infrastructure (eg because Australia needs to reduce its
dependence on rapidly increasing debt to drive economic growth).
My
Interpretation of your article: Regional Australia will make an important
contribution to Australia’s economic future. Major cities have the greatest
potential to create new businesses / jobs. The ACCI put forward proposals to the
Productivity Commission regarding improved planning and infrastructure to help
cities grow. Transport infrastructure is needed to unclog congestion. At present
75% of growth will occur in 4 major cities (Sydney, Melbourne, Brisbane, Perth).
Determining what to build can be tricky – so there is a need to rely on
objective analysis by Infrastructure Australia. However there are limits to
growth by these 4 cities so smaller cities should be targets for growth.
This requires connectivity to existing cities. Record low funding costs make now
an ideal time to invest in infrastructure – but governments should engage
private sector to design, develop, operate, maintain and finance it. Innovative
financing options include value capture and incentives for asset recycling.
Australia has had very poor collaboration between industry and researchers.
Improving performance requires grouping instigators of activity with research
facilities. Thus special innovation zones are envisaged. Silicon Valley is
an example, but Sydney also has an action plan to promote clustering of networks
amongst innovators and entrepreneurs. Half of all jobs growth in Australia is
within 2km radius of Melbourne and Sydney city centres. Success is needed not
just in those major cities, but in all capitals and regional cities.
For decades, information has been recognised by economists (under
so-called new
growth theories) to be the most important driver of economic growth – and
much more significant than inputs of labour and capital.
The concentration of diverse types of information in major cities (and
especially in the CBD) is the reason that they are strongest in creating new
businesses and jobs. Promoting collaboration amongst those involved with
research and the development of new businesses can stimulate growth – though
trying to do this just through establishing ‘innovation zones’ is too narrow.
The potential for innovation / new business development does not just come
from research – eg consider also inventiveness and process enhancement in
existing enterprises. And turning potential innovations into competitively
successful enterprises requires much more than entrepreneurs. Silicon Valley has
succeeded because of the depth of business competencies and organisation
required to finance and support initially-inexperienced entrepreneurs. The whole
of a cities’ economy needs to be linked into networks that can identify
opportunities and provide support to new enterprise development –
not
just entities on particular sites or involved with networking organisations.
How this can potentially be achieved was suggested in Reinventing
the Regions (2010). This involved methods to build on and
build up the competitive advantages that exist in regional communities (ie
by improved access to strategic market and technological intelligence / ideas to
stimulate discovery of opportunities through collaboration by networks who have
or could develop the competencies needed to address them). By creating
increasingly competitive / productive regional industry clusters a high-income
‘magnet’ for regional population growth would emerge.
There are problems with public or subsidised-private
investment in regional land and infrastructure in the hope that developed land
and infrastructure will encourage population growth - for reasons mentioned in
Will
Infrastructure Australia's Project List Meet Australia's Needs? (2016).
In particular:
- Many analysts have warned that Australia has a national debt
problem (ie a very high national debt / GDP ratio and a dependence of rapidly
increasing that debt to drive economic growth) – see
Australia's
Risk of Financial / Banking Crises as Growth is Driven by Rapidly Rising and
Often Misdirected Debt. Thus, for reasons further developed in
More
on Rethinking the Government’s Northern Development Plan (2016) and
Queensland’s
Appalling Governments (2016), traditional expectations that debt-driven
public investment should be used to drive economic / regional growth are likely
to be hazardous because this might not (and often does not) yield significant
gains in GDP for a decade or ever. Emphasis rather needs to be placed on
investments that will generate guaranteed improvements in GDP in the short term.
By creating ‘magnets’ for population growth (ie by building on and building
up regional competitive advantages) a real ‘demand’ for land and
infrastructure investment will emerge in second tier cities and thus: (a)
provide certainty about what is needed; (b) ensure that economic value is really
added from investments in second-tier cities; and (c) reduce the pressure of
population growth in Australia’s 4 major cities;
- Your article validly noted that planning infrastructure is
complex, so it is hard to be sure what is needed. You thus suggested that it is
necessary to rely on ‘objective analysis by Infrastructure Australia’.
However this can’t yield reliable projects. The criteria Infrastructure
Australia considers can identify infrastructure deficiencies. But this will not
allow the details of the investments needed to rectify those deficiencies to be
identified. New infrastructure needs to be integrated with other aspects
of a region’s development. Infrastructure Australia does not have information
about this. Australia’s machinery for planning and developing infrastructure
is a mess (eg because it assumes that central planning can work). That
machinery
needs to repaired rather than being asked to guess where public funds might
usefully be invested.
Developing
regional cities would have many advantages (eg in reducing congestion and the
cost of dealing with it in major existing cities). However the best way to
achieve this is likely to involve creating population growth through market
‘pull’ (ie by building on and building up existing regional competitive
advantages) rather through government ‘push’ (ie by increasing public debts
or by providing government guarantees to ensure land and infrastructure
investment many years in advance of uncertain need).
John Craig
|